942 F2d 1332 William Inglis Sons Baking Company v. Continental Baking Company Inc William Inglis & Sons Baking Company

942 F.2d 1332

1991-2 Trade Cases P 69,524

WILLIAM INGLIS & SONS BAKING COMPANY, Plaintiff-Appellee,
v.
CONTINENTAL BAKING COMPANY, INC., Defendant-Appellant.
WILLIAM INGLIS & SONS BAKING COMPANY, et al., Plaintiffs-Appellants,
v.
CONTINENTAL BAKING COMPANY, INC., et al., Defendants-Appellees.

Nos. 89-15412, 89-15422.

United States Court of Appeals,
Ninth Circuit.

Argued and Submitted June 6, 1990.
Decided Aug. 6, 1991.

John H. Schafer, Covington & Burling, Washington, D.C., for defendant-appellant-cross-appellee.

William A. Wineberg, Broad, Schultz, Larson & Wineberg, San Francisco, Cal., for plaintiff-appellee-cross-appellant.

Appeal from the United States District Court for the Northern District of California.

Before CANBY, NOONAN and RYMER, Circuit Judges.

CANBY, Circuit Judge:

1

A jury found Continental liable to Inglis for violating federal and state antitrust statutes, and awarded damages. In No. 89-15412, Continental appeals the court's denial of its motions for judgment notwithstanding the verdict ("JNOV") and a new trial; we affirm in part and reverse in part. In No. 89-15422, Inglis appeals several of the court's rulings affecting the amount of damages; we affirm in part and reverse in part.

I. FACTS

2

In the 1960s and early 1970s, William Inglis & Sons Baking Company and ITT Continental Baking Company were competing manufacturers of bread products in northern California. Both companies produced and sold, among other things, one-pound loaves of white pan bread that were marketed under the "private labels" of particular retailers. In 1971, Inglis filed this antitrust action, claiming that Continental was seeking to eliminate Inglis and other competitors by charging below-cost and discriminatory prices for private label bread.

3

Inglis alleged that Continental's pricing conduct violated (i) sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2; (ii) section 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a); and (iii) the California Unfair Practices Act, Cal. Bus. & Prof.Code §§ 17000-17101.1 A jury returned a verdict for Inglis on all three claims, and found damages in excess of $5,000,000. On post-trial motions, the court ordered JNOV for Continental, or, in the alternative, a new trial, on the federal claims; and a new trial on the state claim. On appeal, this Court reversed the award of JNOV on the federal claims and affirmed the grant of a new trial on the state claim. Thus, the entire case was tried a second time.

4

The jury again returned a verdict for Inglis on all three claims; it also found damages (before trebling) of approximately $8 million on the Sherman Act claim, $4 million on the Robinson-Patman Act claim, and $10 million on the state law claim. On post-trial motions, the court declined to order JNOV on any claim. It also ruled, however, that the evidence supported a maximum recovery of $5,600,000 on the Sherman Act claim, and $5,600,000 on the state law claim. Inglis agreed to remit the excess as a condition of the court's denial of Continental's new trial motion. Entitled to chose a recovery from among the three claims, Inglis naturally opted to accept $5.6 million (for either the Sherman Act or state law claim) over 4 million (for the Robinson-Patman Act claim). The court trebled this amount to $16,800,000, and then deducted $3,500,000, the sum Inglis received when it sold its assets.2 The final recovery figure was $13,300,000.

5

Continental now appeals from the denial of its motions for JNOV and a new trial; Inglis appeals from the district court's deduction of the $3.5 million from its damage recovery against Continental, and from the court's denial of interest from the date of the first judgment.

II. CONTINENTAL'S APPEAL

6

A. JNOV on Claim of Attempted Monopolization

7

Continental argues that it was entitled to JNOV on Inglis' claim of attempted monopolization because, inter alia, Inglis failed to produce sufficient evidence that Continental acted with anticompetitive intent. We agree. One necessary element of Inglis' case for attempted monopolization under section 2 of the Sherman Act was proof that Continental specifically intended to control prices or destroy competition. See Thurman Industries, Inc. v. Pay 'N Pak Stores, Inc., 875 F.2d 1369, 1378 (9th Cir.1989); Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1027.3 Inglis' evidence, which included an accounting study of Continental price/cost data and testimony about Continental's sales practices, was not adequate to support a finding of such intent.

8

1. Inglis' Price/Cost Study As Evidence of Intent

9

Inglis' principal evidence of intent was also the centerpiece of its entire case, a study prepared by the accounting firm of Ernst & Whinney ("E & W") that compared Continental's price for private label bread with different measures of Continental's cost for producing4 that bread. E & W calculated one measure of cost by (i) identifying the expenses that varied with Continental's total output, (ii) assigning to private label bread a percentage of each of those expenses, the percentage corresponding to private label bread's share of total Continental output, and (iii) dividing the amount resulting from step (ii) by the number of loaves of private label bread sold by Continental.5 The study showed that, between 1970 and 1976, Continental repeatedly sold private label bread at prices that were below this measure of cost. Contrary to Inglis' contentions at trial and on appeal, this data could not serve as sufficient evidence of intent.

10

In order for such a price/cost comparison to support a finding of specific intent to monopolize, the cost measure would have had to include only expenses that were "uniquely incurred" in the production of private label bread. See Marsann Co. v. Brammall, Inc., 788 F.2d 611, 612, 613 (9th Cir.1986). By a "uniquely incurred" expense, we mean one that Continental would not have incurred had it not produced private label bread. See id. at 613. The methodology of the E & W study, however, was to include expenses that Continental may have incurred regardless of its private label bread production. Inglis' cost expert, who supervised the study, testified at trial that he included in private label cost a portion of some expenses, such as those for heating, telephone, supervisors, display space, sanitation labor and supplies, even though these expenses may have been exactly the same had Continental produced no private label bread. In this way, the study failed to identify the unique cost of producing private label bread, and consequently failed to show that Continental's prices were below that cost. This flaw rendered the accounting study insufficient evidence of intent to monopolize.6

2. Other Evidence of Intent

11

Virtually the only other evidence of specific intent that Inglis offered was testimony about an incident in which a Continental salesman offered a certain price to a potential customer on the condition that the customer state in writing that he had received an offer at the same price from another seller. There was, however, no indication that the salesman urged the customer to misstate the truth. Hence, although Inglis interpreted this behavior as improper, it was no more than an effort to verify that Continental offered the price in order to meet competition. The testimony about this incident did not--either by itself or in combination with other evidence--establish that Continental specifically intended to control prices or destroy competition.7

B. JNOV on Claim of Price Discrimination

12

The fate of Inglis' price discrimination claim follows that of its attempted monopolization claim. To make out a case of illegal price discrimination under the Robinson-Patman Act, Inglis needed to prove that Continental "discriminate[d] in price between different purchasers of [bread] of like grade and quality" and that this difference may have tended "to lessen competition or ... to create a monopoly." 15 U.S.C. § 13(a); see Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1040; Texaco, Inc. v. Hasbrouck, --- U.S. ----, 110 S.Ct. 2535, 2542-43, 110 L.Ed.2d 492 (1990). Inglis succeeded in showing that Continental offered the same bread to different customers at different prices, but failed to introduce sufficient evidence of the anticompetitive effect of these differences.

13

Inglis was entitled to demonstrate the necessary effect through a showing of anticompetitive intent. See Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1040.8 Inglis attempted to show that intent by means of the Ernst & Whinney study. However, to serve as sufficient evidence of intent for a price discrimination claim, a price/cost comparison must meet the same standard required to establish intent for an attempted monopolization claim. See id. at 1041. Because the E & W study failed to calculate the cost uniquely incurred in producing private label bread, it could not demonstrate that Continental's price was below that figure. Unable to demonstrate such pricing, the study did not suffice as evidence of anticompetitive intent. Nor was Inglis' other evidence of intent adequate to support a finding of intent. See section A.2 supra.

14

C. JNOV on the California Unfair Practices Claim

15

Continental contends that it was entitled to JNOV on Inglis' claim under California's Unfair Practices Act, Cal. Bus. & Prof.Code sections 17000-17101, because Inglis failed to prove that Continental's pricing had an anticompetitive purpose or caused injury to Inglis, as required under the statute, and because Inglis' damages calculations were below the minimal standard for probative value. We disagree, and affirm the court's denial of JNOV to Continental on this claim.

1. Anticompetitive purpose

16

To establish its claim under the California Unfair Practices Act, Cal. Bus. & Prof.Code sections 17000-17101, Inglis needed to prove that Continental sold bread at "below ... average total cost for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition." Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1048 (citing Cal.Bus. & Prof.Code §§ 17043, 17026, 17029); see Turnbull & Turnbull v. ARA Transportation, Inc., 219 Cal.App.3d 811, 820-23, 268 Cal.Rptr. 856, 861-63 (1990). The statute permitted Inglis "to create a presumption of unlawful purpose by introducing evidence of sales below [average total] cost plus proof of injury to competitors or competition." Id. at 1049 (citing Cal.Bus. & Prof.Code § 17071); see Turnbull, 219 Cal.App.3d at 825, 268 Cal.Rptr. at 864.

17

Continental does not challenge Inglis' figures for Continental's average total cost; nor does it deny that its prices were below average total cost or that Inglis suffered injury. Instead, Continental argues that the statutory presumption was unavailable because Inglis admitted at trial that the market would not have allowed Continental to sell at its average total cost.9 Contrary to Continental's position, this fact did not render the presumption ineffective under state law or place it in conflict with federal law.

18

First, the California legislature did not expressly limit use of § 17071 to situations in which the market would have permitted sales at or above the defendant's average total cost. Even though pricing below average total cost may be legitimate under certain circumstances, see Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1035, the statute allows the factfinder to infer unlawful intent from such pricing (plus injury to competition or competitor) without regard to the peculiar market conditions of the case. Nor are we aware of any California judicial decision creating the restriction Continental urges. Indeed, a handful of California cases treat prices charged by the defendant's competitors (albeit relevant to defenses) as irrelevant to the operation of § 17071, which suggests that state courts may well consider market price to be irrelevant also. See Page v. Bakersfield Uniform & Towel Supply Co., 239 Cal.App.2d 762, 770, 49 Cal.Rptr. 46 (1966); Kofsky v. Smart and Final Iris Co., 131 Cal.App.2d 530, 531-31, 281 P.2d 5 (1955); Sandler v. Gordon, 94 Cal.App.2d 254, 258, 210 P.2d 314 (1949). As a federal court sitting in diversity, we are unable to read so clear a state statute as § 17071 in the restrictive way Continental urges without any indication that the state legislature or state courts have adopted or are tending toward such a position.

19

Second, the inference permitted by § 17071 does not become irrational by virtue of the fact that Continental could not have sold at or above its average total cost.10 There is nothing inherently impossible about selling below average total cost for the purpose of injuring a competitor in a market that would not permit the seller to recover average total cost. For example, a seller may choose to sell below a market price that is itself below average total cost in order to weaken or destroy a competitor. This is, in fact, Inglis' claim: although Continental could not have sold at average total cost, it could have sold at a price higher than the one it actually charged.11 On these facts, we find nothing anomalous in the operation of section 17071.12

20

Finally, although Continental introduced evidence tending to justify its price as designed to meet competitors' offers, it did not prevail as a matter of law on this issue. Given that the jury rejected Continental's explanation, we may not accept it unless the evidence "supported only one reasonable conclusion--that [Continental's] lower prices were a good faith response to competition." Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1045 (emphasis removed). Testimony at trial tending to show that Continental led at least one price decrease and failed carefully to verify competitors' prices before "meeting" them prevents us from adopting Continental's explanation as the only reasonable conclusion. See id. at 1047-48, 1050.

2. Causation13

21

In order to establish liability against Continental, Inglis was required to prove " 'the existence of some causal connection between defendant's wrongful act and some loss of anticipated revenue.' " See Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1051 (quoting Flintkote Co. v. Lysfjord, 246 F.2d 368, 392 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 355 U.S. 835, 78 S.Ct. 54, 2 L.Ed.2d 46 (1957)). To satisfy this requirement, Inglis introduced expert testimony that Inglis' profit on private label bread from 1970 to 1976 as well as the company's "going concern" value at the time it was sold in 1976 would have been higher, by specifically stated amounts, had Continental not engaged in below-cost pricing. According to Continental, this testimony was insufficient evidence of causation because other factors, such as the prices charged by other bread producers, influenced the extent of the claimed aggregate loss. Having accepted arguendo Continental's assertion about these additional influences, we nevertheless reject this argument.

22

Continental argues as follows: because Inglis claimed that all of the stated lost profits and lost going concern value were caused by Continental, it may establish the causation element of its case only by proof that all of these losses were caused by Continental; failure to prove that some particular part of the claimed loss was caused by Continental negates the causation element altogether and warrants judgment for Continental.14 Continental's theory is erroneous. According to our caselaw, Inglis was able to satisfy the causation requirement by "establish[ing] that the anticompetitive activities were a material cause of some of its injury"; whether Inglis proved that Continental caused all of the claimed injury is properly an issue affecting only the amount of damages proved. Dolphin Tours, Inc. v. Pacifico Creative Service, 773 F.2d 1506, 1510 (9th Cir.1985) (emphasis supplied); see also Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 114 & n. 9, 89 S.Ct. 1562, 1571 & n. 9, 23 L.Ed.2d 129 (1969) ("[The plaintiff's] burden of proving the fact of damage under section 4 of the Clayton Act is satisfied by its proof of some damage flowing from the unlawful conspiracy; inquiry beyond this minimum point goes only to the amount and not the fact of damage." (emphasis in original)).

23

Continental does not dispute that Inglis' evidence was sufficient to show that Continental's pricing was a material cause of at least some of Inglis' claimed injury. For purposes of this appeal, then, Inglis has succeeded in establishing the causation element of its case.15

3. Damages calculations

24

Having shown a causal connection between the unlawful conduct and an injury to itself, Inglis was required to provide "sufficient evidence to permit 'a just and reasonable estimate of the damages.' " Los Angeles Memorial Coliseum Comm'n v. National Football League, 791 F.2d 1356, 1360 (9th Cir.1986) (quoting Handgards, Inc. v. Ethicon, Inc., 743 F.2d 1282, 1297 (9th Cir.1984), cert. denied, 469 U.S. 1190, 105 S.Ct. 963, 83 L.Ed.2d 968 (1985). This is a "liberal proof of damages standard," Handgards, 743 F.2d at 1297; it is designed to ensure a quantification of injury that is "approximat[e]" rather than highly precise and certain, Dolphin Tours, Inc. v. Pacifico Creative Service, Inc., 773 F.2d 1506, 1511 (9th Cir.1985) (citing Story Parchment Co. v. Paterson Parchment Paper Co., 282 U.S. 555, 563, 51 S.Ct. 248, 250, 75 L.Ed. 544 (1931); see also Texaco, Inc. v. Hasbrouck, --- U.S. ----, 110 S.Ct. 2535, 2551, 110 L.Ed.2d 492 (1990). The economic calculations prepared by Inglis' cost expert satisfied that standard in establishing a portion, but far from all, of the $5.6 million damages figure.

25

One component of Inglis' damages was lost profits during the period of Continental's below-cost pricing. Ernst & Whinney demonstrated that in the second quarter of 1970, just prior to the onset of below-cost pricing, Continental's price for private label bread was 3.1 above a certain measure of its cost16 for producing that bread. E & W then calculated what Continental's price would have been had it maintained that spread throughout the period of below-cost pricing, and projected the profit that Inglis would have made had it been able to sell bread at that price (rather than having to match Continental's below-cost price). The result was a lost profits figure of $2 million.17 We agree with Continental that the evidentiary base underlying this calculation was insufficient.

26

Continental's primary objection is to the use of the second quarter of 1970 as the base period; it contends that no evidence showed that quarter to be " 'similar [to the liability period] but for the impact of the violation.' " Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1052 (quoting Pacific Coast Agricultural Export Ass'n v. Sunkist Growers, Inc., 526 F.2d 1196, 1207 (9th Cir.1975), cert. denied, 425 U.S. 959, 96 S.Ct. 1741, 48 L.Ed.2d 204 (1976)). We agree.

27

Inglis' expert testified that he selected the second quarter of 1970 because it was immediately prior to the alleged below-cost pricing. He also testified that subsequent quarters differed from the base period because pricing was below average variable cost. Neither he nor anyone else, however, offered evidence that market conditions existing during the base period remained the same (or even comparable after appropriate adjustments) during the liability period ending in 1975. Continental offered considerable evidence that conditions differed; prices of ingredients and fuel increased, captives expanded their share of the market, and consumer tastes continued to move away from white pan bread.18 In light of the total absence of contrary evidence by Inglis, its calculation of lost profits is wholly speculative. The district court accordingly erred in failing to award Continental judgment notwithstanding the verdict on Inglis' claim for $2 million in lost profits.19

28

The other component of Inglis' requested damages was lost going concern value. E & W computed this component by restating Inglis' sales for 1975 to show what they would have been had it maintained its 1970 market share, and multiplying that amount by 1.7% to reflect projected pre-tax profits; E & W then discounted this amount to a present value of $3.6 million. We accept Continental's contention that no sufficient evidence supported the assumption of a 1.7% profit margin.

29

The E & W expert testified that Inglis' actual performance in 1975 was a function of depressed market conditions, and that he therefore consulted a survey of baking company profit margins published in the 1975 edition of the "Almanac of Business & Industrial Financial Ratios." The profit margin for surveyed companies that he assumed were "comparable" to Inglis was 1.7%, and he selected it as appropriate for Inglis' projected performance in a nondepressed market. The 1.7% figure, he explained, was below both the average for companies in the survey, and the Northern California industry standard profit. However, the expert was unable to identify any particular significant respect in which Inglis was "comparable" to the surveyed companies. In light of the absence of any meaningful economic similarity between Inglis and these other companies, the use of their profit margins to project Inglis' earnings was mere speculation.

30

Nevertheless, despite the illegitimacy of the 1.7% profit figure, Inglis was entitled to some recovery for lost going concern value. At trial, Inglis offered, as an alternative to the 1.7% figure, its actual 1975 profit margin of .8%; on this basis, it calculated lost going concern value, discounted to present value, at $1.8 million. Continental does not challenge the accuracy of the .8% figure, and it obviously is not an entirely speculative basis for projecting Inglis' earnings after 1975. Thus, the evidence supported a recovery for lost going concern value of $1.8 million.

31

In summary, then, the total damages for which Inglis has shown adequate support in the record are $1.8 million, representing lost going concern value. On remand, the district court should therefore reduce the untrebled damages award from $5.6 million to $1.8 million.D. New Trial on California Claim

32

Continental urges that the district court's denial of its motion for a new trial was reversible error because the jury verdict was against the weight of the evidence. We cannot agree. The court's denial of Continental's new trial motion displayed none of the abuses for which we may reverse such a decision: the record did not lack evidence supporting the verdict; the court did not believe that it was without power to grant a new trial; the court did not fail to weigh the evidence, or weigh it according to the wrong standard; and the court did not deny the motion despite finding that the verdict was against the weight of the evidence. See Landes Constr. Co., Inc. v. Royal Bank of Canada, 833 F.2d 1365, 1372 (9th Cir.1987). The court's decision, therefore, was within its discretion. See id. at 1371-72.

E. Postjudgment Interest

33

On February 4, 1987, after the jury returned verdicts on liability and damages, the district court entered a "judgment" for three times the amounts specified in the verdicts, but provided that Inglis was "entitled to receive only the highest of such judgments, after appropriate set-offs, if any." Eventually, the court reduced the jury's verdict through remittitur and a set-off, and on February 24, 1989, entered another "judgment," and indicated that Inglis should receive interest from February 4, 1987.

34

Emphasizing that the court retained jurisdiction after February 4, 1987 in order to entertain motions that could affect the amount of damages, Continental claims that the order of that date could not properly trigger interest accrual. The applicable California Code provision states that "interest commences to accrue on a money judgment on the date of entry of the judgment." Cal.Code Civ.P. § 685.020.20 Continental has offered us no further enlightenment on this subject, and our own research indicates that the California courts have not confronted the issue presented here. Left with only the bare statute for guidance, we conclude that the court's award of interest from the earlier order was not error. Inasmuch as that decision allowed interest to accrue from the entry of what was by its own terms a "judgment" for money damages, it was consistent with the plain language of the statute. Cf. Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical Corp. v. Bonjorno, 494 U.S. 827, 110 S.Ct. 1570, 1573, 1576, 108 L.Ed.2d 842 (1990) (holding that interest on federal claim began to accrue when district court entered judgment soon after verdict, even though court later entertained JNOV motion and reduced amount of judgment).

F. Setoff After Trebling

35

Campbell-Taggart paid Inglis $3.5 million to purchase Inglis' business and settle the antitrust claims that Inglis had brought against Campbell-Taggart.21 Continental argues that the district court should have deducted this amount22 before, rather than after, trebling Inglis' judgment against Continental. Our precedent, however, is to the contrary.

36

In Flintkote Co. v. Lysfjord, 246 F.2d 368 (9th Cir.1957), the plaintiff sued two defendants for conspiracy in violation of antitrust statutes. Before trial, the plaintiff settled with one defendant for $20,000. The jury returned a verdict against the other defendant for $50,000. The district court trebled the amount to $150,000, then deducted the $20,000 settlement recovery. We upheld this procedure, reasoning that the jury verdict, in combination with a treble damages provision, entitled the plaintiff to a total of $150,000; and, unless the $20,000 was deducted from the trebled amount, the plaintiff would not recover what he was entitled to.

37

We apply Flintkote 's reasoning to this case as follows. The verdict, as amended by the remittitur and further adjusted in Section C, supra, set the damages against Continental at $1.8 million. State law provides for trebling that figure, entitling Inglis to a recovery of $5.4 million. Only by deducting the Campbell-Taggart recovery after trebling can we allow Inglis the full benefit of its entitlement. We therefore so direct.

38

Continental urges that Los Angeles Memorial Coliseum Comm'n v. National Football League, 791 F.2d 1356 (9th Cir.1986), is dispositive of the issue in the present case. Coliseum, however, dealt with a critically different situation. There, the jury's verdict was found to have aggregated two alternative measures of the amount of antitrust injury suffered by the plaintiff. See id. at 1368, 1375 ("[T]he [plaintiffs] have been awarded [before trebling] double the compensatory relief to which they are entitled. In order to treble only a single measure of compensatory relief, this double recovery must be corrected before trebling."). In contrast, the (remitted) verdict in this case derives from only one measure of Inglis' injury. Hence, Coliseum is inapposite and does not dictate that the Campbell-Taggart payment should have been set off before trebling.

III. INGLIS' CROSS APPEAL

39

A. Effect of Remittitur on Inglis' Right To Appeal

40

Continental argues that Inglis relinquished its right to appeal the rulings on setoff and postjudgment interest by accepting a remitted verdict. Both the Supreme Court and this court, however, have described the waiver implicit in remittitur as a narrow one that involves only the right to appeal the reduction of damages effected by the remittitur. See Donovan v. Penn Shipping Co., 429 U.S. 648, 649, 97 S.Ct. 835, 836, 51 L.Ed.2d 112 (1977) (approving the appellate court's enforcement of "the settled rule that a plaintiff who has accepted a remittitur may not appeal to seek reinstatement of the original verdict" (emphasis supplied)); 999 v. C.I.T. Corp., 776 F.2d 866, 873 (9th Cir.1985) ("[T]he plaintiff cannot contest the validity of a remittitur to which he has consented." (emphasis supplied)); see also 6A Moore's Federal Practice 59.08 (2d ed.1989) at 203-05 (observing that plaintiff may not appeal from remittitur order he has accepted, but may appeal from "other parts of the judgment." Id., at 205.).

41

Continental contends further that, regardless of the general rule on appealing from remitted judgments, the particular order in this case embodied an understanding by Inglis and the court that Inglis would not appeal the rulings on setoff and interest. To the contrary, however, Inglis has demonstrated that no such understanding existed. In the postjudgment proceedings below, Inglis and Continental waged a battle of proposed orders on just this point, with Continental urging the court to issue a remittitur that barred Inglis from appealing these rulings. Ultimately, the court rejected Continental's proposal and accepted Inglis' proposed order, which contained no such bar.

42

B. Interest From Date of Judgment After First Trial

43

Inglis maintains that it was entitled to have postjudgment interest accrue from the date judgment was entered after the first trial.23 This contention is contrary to the Supreme Court's decision in Bonjorno.24 In that case, judgment ("I") was entered after the jury returned a verdict for the plaintiff; subsequently, the district court concluded that the evidence as to damages was insufficient, and ordered a new trial. On a limited retrial, the jury awarded even more damages to the plaintiff, and judgment ("II") was entered; subsequently, the court ordered JNOV to the defendant on a portion of the damages. The appeals court reversed the JNOV and reinstated judgment II. The Supreme Court ruled that interest did not accrue from judgment I because it was "legally insufficient." 110 S.Ct. at 1576-78. In the present case, the 1978 judgment for Inglis also was legally insufficient, requiring a new trial (not only on damages but on liability as well). Following the reasoning in Kaiser, we hold that it was proper for the district court not to award interest from that judgment.

44

C. The Deduction of the Campbell-Taggart Payment

45

Inglis argues that the court erred in deducting the $3.5 million Campbell-Taggart payment from the award of damages. Inglis makes two points: (1) only $800,000 of the payment was in settlement of Inglis' antitrust claims; (2) not even the $800,000 should have been deducted since it was not compensation for injury for which Continental was found liable.

1. The settlement portion

46

The trial court found that the entire $3.5 million paid by Campbell-Taggart to Inglis was paid in settlement of the lawsuit. That finding is clearly erroneous. It would attribute no value at all to Inglis' land, plant and equipment. The agreement between Inglis and Campbell-Taggart clearly indicated that $800,000 was being paid in settlement of Inglis' antitrust claims, and that $2,700,000 was being paid for the land and buildings of Inglis' baking operation. The $800,000 settlement of the lawsuit was expressly made binding whether or not the sale of assets for $2.7 million went through. Furthermore, at the trial Inglis' expert specifically excluded the value of the baking plant from the damage calculations he proposed to the jury. See RT at 2046. Cf. Standard Oil Co. of California v. Moore, 251 F.2d 188, 219-20 (9th Cir.1957), cert. denied, 356 U.S. 975, 78 S.Ct. 1139, 2 L.Ed.2d 1148 (1958) (recognizing lost "good will" as separate from tangible assets in assessing damages). Thus, at a minimum, the court erred by deducting any more than $800,000 of the Campbell-Taggart payment from the damage award.

2. Deduction of the settlement amount

47

Inglis argues that the damage figure adopted by the jury was for injury caused by Continental and no one else, and that any deduction because of Campbell-Taggart's settlement is consequently improper.

48

There is more than one reason why we cannot accept Inglis' argument. The first is that the claims asserted by Inglis against Campbell-Taggart and Continental in this case were coextensive. Indeed, they both were alleged to have combined and conspired with each other and others to bring about all of the injuries to Inglis' business for which relief was sought. Campbell-Taggart settled those claims without narrowing them in any way; Continental chose to litigate and lost. The prospect of a double recovery is clear if no deduction is made.

49

This case is consequently distinguishable from Convoy Corp. v. Sperry Rand Corp., 601 F.2d 385 (9th Cir.1979). In Convoy, we agreed that equity required an offset to prevent double recovery, but determined that the offset should be only partial because the claims against the two successive, independent tortfeasors were not coextensive; the claim that was settled included damages for lost profits and punitive damages, relief which was not sought against the non-settling defendant. Here there is no basis for excluding a part of the Campbell-Taggart settlement as inapplicable to the claim asserted against Continental. Cf. Franklin Supply Co. v. Tolman, 454 F.2d 1059, 1072 (9th Cir.1972) (recovery of damages for over-evaluation of shares impermissible when equivalent relief had already been obtained in settlement of "same claims" asserted against another).

50

Inglis argues that the settlement payment by Campbell-Taggart could not duplicate any of the award against Continental because the verdict was for damages caused by Continental alone. Inglis points to the jury instruction that Inglis was not to be held liable for loss resulting from the actions of others. Other instructions, however, informed the jury that injuries were proximately caused by an act if that act "played a substantial part in bringing about or actually causing the injury or damage;" that an antitrust violation proximately caused an injury if the violation "was a material cause of any injury to plaintiffs, even though other factors may have contributed to plaintiff's injury;" and that plaintiffs could recover for injuries suffered "because of" violations by Continental. Taken as a whole, these instructions permitted the jury to award damages against Continental for wrongs committed by Continental even though other parties such as Campbell-Taggart might have been contributed somewhat to the same injuries.

51

Inglis argues that the evidence does not support a suggestion that Campbell-Taggart contributed to the post-1970 injuries for which Continental was held liable; Campbell-Taggart appeared from the evidence to follow Continental's lead, as did others, in the post-1970 period. The short answer to this argument is that the question at issue concerns the scope of the claim against Campbell-Taggart as it was actually settled, not the scope of that claim as it might later be derived from evidence in litigation of which Campbell-Taggart was no longer a part. We have no way of knowing what the evidence against Campbell-Taggart would have been if it had not settled. We cannot assume, and the evidence cannot be viewed as establishing, that prices charged by Campbell-Taggart in the post-1976 period were necessarily in compliance with California law. They were claimed not to be, and that claim was settled.

52

We conclude, therefore, that the trial court did not err in deducting from the trebled verdict $800,000 of the settlement payment made by Campbell-Taggart to Inglis.

IV. CONCLUSIONS

53

In Continental's appeal, we reverse the district court's denial of JNOV on the Sherman Act and Robinson-Patman Act claims. We reverse the denial of JNOV on the state law claim only as to the award for lost profits; in all other respects, we affirm the denial of JNOV and new trial on the state law claim. We accordingly reduce the untrebled damages total to $1.8 million. We also affirm the court's decision to award interest from the date of entry of the earlier order of judgment (February 4, 1987) entered in this, second trial, and to set off the reduced Campbell-Taggart payment after, rather than before, trebling.

54

In Inglis' cross-appeal, we affirm the district court's refusal to award interest from the date of judgment on the first trial, and amend its setoff decision so that Inglis' recovery, after trebling, is reduced by only $800,000.

55

The order of the district court is AFFIRMED IN PART, REVERSED IN PART, AND AMENDED IN PART. The case is REMANDED for entry of judgment in accordance with this opinion.

56

Each party will bear its own costs on this appeal.

57

NOONAN, Circuit Judge, concurring and dissenting:

58

To understand this case one must begin with a description of the market as established by the evidence at trial.

THE MARKET

59

Geography. A given bakery can provide fresh bread for only a relatively small area, covering a radius of no more than 200 miles. See In the Matter of International Tel. & Tel. Corp., 104 F.T.C. 280, 409 (1984). The San Francisco area, the Lake Tahoe area, and the Sacramento area were the principal loci of competition of the bakers involved here. Northern California is the relevant geographic area.

60

The Product. The product is bread--bread eventually to be consumed by the eaters of bread. Arguably all breads are interchangeable, and variety and heath-baked breads such as whole wheat, rye, pumpernickel, and raisin are part of the same market as white pan bread. However, this case was tried on the basis that the white pan loaf was the product, and this single kind of bread must be the focus of decision.

61

The white pan loaf was produced by bakeries in three ways: (1) advertised bread, as to which there was a brand name that was publicly advertised; (2) private label bread, bread that was not advertised under a brand name but sold by individual retailers as their bread, although it had been purchased from wholesalers; and (3) bread from the "captive bakeries," that is, bakeries maintained by major grocery chains.

62

Inglis has maintained that the market is further limited to the white pan loaf sold by wholesalers to retailers as "private label." Inglis' expert, Professor Wheeler, testified that such a submarket existed. His testimony is contrary to the accepted legal definition of a submarket. A submarket can be determined by examining "industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the product's peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors." Brown Shoe Co. Inc. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 1524, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962). The private label market is not recognized as a separate economic entity. The bread sold in it does not have any peculiar characteristics and uses. Unique production facilities are not employed to produce the bread. The customers are not distinct and there are no specialized vendors. Price changes are sensitive not only to the price for private label but to the cost of captive bakery bread. In short, there is only a single characteristic that is peculiar to private label bread: distinct prices. That is not enough to establish a submarket.

63

"Private label" bread is no different in kind or quality from advertised or "captive bakery bread." In each of these categories, there is simply white pan bread. Chemically and physically, it is the same thing. The only difference is the price at which the bread is sold. Where the product is the same, a difference in its pricing does not create a different product or a different market. A market is "composed of products that have reasonable interchangeability for the purposes for which they are produced." United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 404, 76 S.Ct. 994, 1012, 100 L.Ed. 1264 (1956). This definition is long-established and still current. State of California v. American Stores Co., 872 F.2d 837, 841 (9th Cir.1989) rev'd on other grounds, 495 U.S. 271, 110 S.Ct. 1853, 109 L.Ed.2d 240 (1990). One pound white loaves of bread are produced to eat. The three kinds of bread were interchangeable. The market here was the market for these breads in Northern California.

64

The Competitors. As of 1970 when this case began, the following bakeries were competitors in this market:

65

Campbell-Taggart, a national company, which sold advertised "Kilpatrick" and "Rainbo" brands and private label bread. In the period 1970 to 1975 it operated six bakeries in the relevant area and made from 41 to 52 percent of the wholesalers' sales.

66

American, which operated the largest bakery in the market and sold advertised bread chiefly under the brand name "Langendorf" and private label bread. Until 1973 it was the second largest wholesaler in the market.

67

Continental, the largest national wholesale bakery in the United States, but only the third largest wholesaler in the relevant market. It sold advertised bread under the label "Wonder" and private label bread. From 1970 through 1975 it made 22 percent of the wholesalers' sales.

68

Inglis, the plaintiff in this case. It operated one bakery, located in Stockton, and sold advertised bread under the Sunbeam label and private label bread. In 1969, prior to the events in this lawsuit, it declared bankruptcy, but apparently emerged to continue business through 1975. Beginning in 1965 until 1975, Inglis lost money every year except 1972 when, for part of the period, Campbell-Taggart and Continental were closed by a strike. Since 1966 Inglis did not reinvest enough capital to cover depreciation. Because of its financial difficulties Inglis had effectively stopped advertising its Sunbeam brand by the mid-1960s. In 1975, because of irregularities in Inglis' books, the company financing it withdrew its support. Inglis made one last attempt to secure financing from the Teamsters Union and then folded. This suit, now in its twentieth year, appears to be its chief asset.

69

Safeway, Lucky and Alpha Beta. These three large grocery chains baked and sold about half the bread in the white pan bread market.

70

Interstate Bread Company, a national bakery selling advertised bread under the Blue Seal label.

71

Welsh's Baking Co., a regional company selling advertised bread under the Sheepherder label.

72

Other wholesalers: Cottage, Home Craft, Modern, Nielson.

73

In summary, there were five national and five regional wholesale bakeries and three large grocery chains in the Northern California market. It is undisputed that these bakers had excess capacity for the production of bread. There was ample evidence that the price of the bread was dominated by the three chains which produced their own bread and could produce more of it if the price went up beyond the price they preferred.

74

THE SHERMAN ACT CLAIM OF ATTEMPTED MONOPOLIZATION

75

Inglis failed to prove this claim, and Continental is entitled to judgment notwithstanding the verdict for three reasons:

76

First. Although Professor Wheeler testified that there was such a thing as a market in private label white pan bread, the evidence adduced at trial was overwhelmingly to the contrary, as the above description of the market shows. It is the plaintiff's burden to establish the relevant market. R.C. Dick Geothermal Corp. v. Thermogenics, Inc., 890 F.2d 139, 143 (9th Cir.1989) (en banc). The proper market is a question of fact and a jury finding will be reversed if clearly erroneous. Twin City Sportservice, Inc. v. Charles O. Finley & Company, 676 F.2d 1291, 1299 (9th Cir.), cert. denied 459 U.S. 1009, 103 S.Ct. 364, 74 L.Ed.2d 400 (1982).

77

Inglis' failure to prove a special market in private label white bread ends its case. It has offered no proof of predation in the sale of advertised bread. Yet sales of private label and advertised bread must be aggregated if a case in the relevant market is to be made. See In the Matter of International Tel. & Tel. Corp., 104 F.T.C. at 435. The "ultimate standard" is whether the alleged predation created "a market structure enabling the seller to recoup his losses." William Inglis & Sons Baking Co. v. I.T.T. Continental Baking Co., Inc., 668 F.2d 1014, 1035 (9th Cir.1981) (Inglis I ), cert. denied, 459 U.S. 825, 103 S.Ct. 57, 74 L.Ed.2d 61 (1982). Nothing has been proved by Inglis as to a market structure that includes advertised white bread.

78

Second. As a distinct and independent ground for decision, it may be accepted arguendo that the market contended for by Inglis was the private label white pan bread sold by the wholesalers, but the claim that Continental had a predatory strategy is implausible.

79

Four characteristics of this market are of capital importance for this case: (1) Continental's sales in the relevant period were no more than half that of the largest wholesale baker in the market, Campbell-Taggart. (2) Inglis was a small and weak competitor that had declared bankruptcy before the conduct complained of began. (3) The grocery chains played a key role in the pricing of private label bread because if the price rose the chains could use their captives. (4) All of the wholesalers had substantial excess baking capacity.

80

As evidence of a predatory scheme, Inglis points to the testimony of Professor Wheeler that in "an oligopolistic or duopolistic market with barriers to entry" a firm would raise prices because the higher prices would "be beneficial to all participants in the market." This testimony is not helpful to Inglis' case. The fact that all participants would benefit would mean that Inglis would benefit too; the market strategy would not have a negative impact on Inglis.

81

Inglis also offered Professor Wheeler's testimony that a rational businessman might engage in predatory pricing as part of "a long-term market strategy to achieve market penetration and eliminate competitors." Such a possibility theoretically exists. But to testify that the possibility exists is not to testify that a rational businessman in Continental's shoes would so have behaved in the Northern California white pan bread market. This piece of testimony proves nothing concretely.

82

Entry barrier is irrelevant where excess capacity exists. Competition cannot be eliminated or market discipline imposed where major consumers possess their own alternative ways of getting the product. Even if Professor Wheeler's testimony is believed that there were entry barriers for new bakers, a predatory strategy would have been unproductive for Continental because it would have opened the field to its larger competitor, Campbell-Taggart, to use its excess capacity, and because the chains would have continued to hold the key to price.

83

"Absent some assurance that the hoped-for monopoly will materialize, and that it can be sustained for a significant period of time," a predator would embark on a highly speculative and economically irrational scheme. Matsushita Elec. Indust. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 589, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 1357, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986) (emphasis in original). It is for that reason that "predatory pricing schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful." Id. In the highly competitive white pan bread market, Continental had no hope of achieving monopoly power and no prospect of sustaining it.

84

The ultimate purpose of the antitrust laws, federal and state, is to benefit the consumer. Such is "the modern conception." American Academic Suppliers, Inc. v. Beckley-Cardy, Inc., 922 F.2d 1317, 1319 (7th Cir.1991). "[M]istaken inferences" about predation "are especially costly, because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect." Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 594, 106 S.Ct. at 1360. Here a case that has gone on twenty years has ended in a multimillion dollar verdict imposed on a baker because its price for bread was too low! To sustain the verdict would violate federal antitrust law as it is now authoritatively interpreted.

85

Third. As Judge Canby's opinion demonstrates, Inglis completely failed to show that Continental acted with anticompetitive intent, that is, as he puts it, that it "specifically intended to control prices or destroy competition." In Judge Canby's words, "Inglis' principal evidence of intent was also the centerpiece of its entire case, a study prepared by the accounting firm of Ernst & Whinney." The "methodology of the E & W study" was, as he says, "to include expenses that Continental may have incurred regardless of its private label bread production." As a consequence, the study "failed to identify the unique cost of producing private label bread, and consequently failed to show Continental's prices were below that cost."

INGLIS' ROBINSON-PATMAN ACT CLAIM

86

As Judge Canby has concluded, the failure of the E & W study to show intent to monopolize is also failure to show evidence of intent to discriminate in prices in order to lessen competition or create a monopoly. As Judge Canby has also concluded, Inglis' market analysis "failed to show the substantial possibility of injury to competition." Again Continental is entitled to judgment notwithstanding the verdict.

THE CALIFORNIA UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES CLAIM

87

The Law of the Case. Inglis I established there was a single difference between the Sherman Act and California antitrust law:

88

The only real difference between the California statute and federal law is in the allocation of evidentiary burdens. Assuming proof of injury to a competitor has been made, California law allows plaintiffs to establish a prima facie case with proof of prices below average total cost. The defendant then has the burden of negating the inference of illegal intent or of establishing an affirmative defense. Under federal law, a plaintiff who relies on prices below average total cost, but above average variable cost, has not created a presumption of illegal intent.

89

Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1049.

90

Unless there is "manifest injustice," the law of the case binds us. See United States v. Miller, 822 F.2d 828, 832 (9th Cir.1987). No manifest injustice has been shown in adhering to what we earlier laid down as the governing law. To the contrary, injustice is done when a case which was tried twice, and considered here once as a federal case, should in the end be decided by an unsupported theory of what state law might be. That this case is still conceived of by the majority as a federal case is indicated by its citation of federal authority on damages said to be awardable under California law.

91

In particular, in a way that is fatal to Inglis' case, we are committed to the following standard as to what constitutes predatory pricing:

92

Predation exists when the justification of these prices is based, not on their effectiveness in minimizing losses, but on their tendency to eliminate rivals and create a market structure enabling the seller to recoup his losses. This is the ultimate standard, and not rigid adherence to a particular cost-based rule, that must govern our analysis of alleged predatory pricing.

93

Guided by these principles, we hold that to establish predatory pricing a plaintiff must prove that the anticipated benefits of defendant's price depended on its tendency to discipline or eliminate competition and thereby enhance the firm's long-term ability to reap the benefits of monopoly power.

94

Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1035.

95

This standard, enunciated in relation to the Sherman Act, has, under the law of the case, equal application to the California antitrust law. It is clearly a standard different from older decisions that treated predation as something that could be proved apart from a relevant market, e.g., Blanton v. Mobil Oil Corp., 721 F.2d 1207, 1214 (9th Cir.1983), cert. denied, 471 U.S. 1007, 105 S.Ct. 1874, 85 L.Ed.2d 166 (1985). The change is consistent with modern Supreme Court precedent, e.g., Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 119-20 n. 15, 107 S.Ct. 484, n. 15, 93 L.Ed.2d 427 (1986).

96

As Inglis I makes explicit, predatory pricing can be proved only by considering its effect on "a market structure." Predatory pricing does not take place in a void. It is predatory only if it is designed to affect the market structure. To determine whether Continental's pricing here was predatory, we must first determine what the market was that it is charged with affecting.

97

As the earlier description of the market demonstrated, Inglis attempted to show an impact on a nonexistent private label white pan bread market. No impact was shown on the actual market in white pan bread. Inglis' failure of proof in this respect is a failure to prove predatory pricing.

98

The California Law. The foregoing has proceeded on the assumption that we are bound by the law of the case set out in Inglis I. But there is no inconsistency between California law and the law of the case. Inglis I merely took up a question which California had not explicitly addressed. Already, the language of Inglis I on the difference between the two statutes consisting in the burden of proof is being cited as authoritative in the state courts. Turnbull & Turnbull v. ARA Transp., Inc., 219 Cal.App.3d 811, 825, 268 Cal.Rptr. 856, 864 (1990).

99

Contrary to the wooden interpretation of a single section of the statute that the majority has adopted here, California has been careful to explain that the statute has a purpose as a whole: "Throughout the Act the Legislature has manifested its intent to discourage practices which injure the seller's competitors (§§ 17040, 17043, 17045, 17071) and thereby tend to create the monopolies condemned by section 17001 (ante, fn. 3). Equally apparent is the Legislature's concern to allow the seller to meet in good faith the prices of his competitors (§§ 17040, 17050), thereby fostering the competition promoted by section 17001." Harris v. Capitol Records Distributing Corp., 64 Cal.2d 454, 50 Cal.Rptr. 539, 544, 413 P.2d 139 (1966). The purpose is to prevent the creation of monopolies. It is for that reason that the statute does not put into play the presumption on which the majority relies simply by proof of sales below cost but only when that proof is joined "with proof of the injurious effect of such acts." Cal.Bus. & Prof.Code § 17071 (West 1987). There has been no proof of the injurious effects of the acts attributed to Continental.

100

For the same reason, the legislature made it easy to defeat the presumption, and the Supreme Court of California has made it even easier. The presumption does not apply to any sale made "[i]n an endeavor made in good faith to meet the legal prices of a competitor selling the same article or product, in the same locality or trade area and in the ordinary channels of trade." Id. at § 17050(d).

101

The standard set for how a defendant may rebut the presumption created by the statute is as follows:

102

The obvious and only effect of this provision is to require the defendants to go forward with such proof as would bring them within one of the exceptions or which would negative the prima facie showing of wrongful intent. They may present facts showing that they were within the express exceptions regardless of actual intent; or they may introduce evidence of another necessity not expressly included to show that sales were made in good faith and not for the purpose of injuring competitors or destroying competition.

103

People v. Pay Less Drug Store, 25 Cal.2d 108, 114, 153 P.2d 9 (1944).

104

The subsequent application of Pay Less has established that testimony by the seller as to his intention to meet competition and to maintain and hopefully expand his sales by selling below cost is sufficient to rebut the statutory presumption of an intent to injure competitors or to destroy competition. Dooley's Hardware Mart v. Food Giant Markets, Inc., 21 Cal.App.3d 513, 98 Cal.Rptr. 543 (1971); Ellis v. Dallas, 113 Cal.App.2d 234, 248 P.2d 63 (1952); Sandler v. Gordon, 94 Cal.App.2d 254, 210 P.2d 314 (1949). The simple denial of the seller of his intent to injure competition has sufficed as evidence to rebut the presumption. Tri-Q, Inc. v. Sta-Hi Corp., 63 Cal.2d 199, 45 Cal.Rptr. 878, 883, 404 P.2d 486, 491 (1965).

105

The Supreme Court of California has not decided the precise issue of recoupment. Nonetheless, the liberal decisions of the supreme and appellate courts of California permitting easy refutation of the presumption are data not to be disregarded unless we are convinced by other persuasive data that the California Supreme Court would decide otherwise. Dimidowich v. Bell and Howell, 803 F.2d 1473, 1482 (9th Cir.1986) modified on other grounds, 810 F.2d 1517 (1987). The data we have all point in the same direction.

106

Our basic task "when we decide a claim that involves a novel question of state law" is to "try to predict how the highest state court would decide the issue." Hal Roach Studios, Inc. v. Richard Feiner & Co., Inc., 896 F.2d 1542, 1548 (9th Cir.1990). In making such a prediction we "may also look to 'well reasoned-decisions from other jurisdictions.' " Id. (citation omitted). It seems reasonably clear that an informed prediction as to how the present Supreme Court of California would decide this case would recognize that the California Supreme Court would take into account modern federal law and decide this case as United States Supreme Court precedent dictates federal law would decide it.

107

In the present case Inglis' own expert testified that because of the excess capacity in the market Continental had to sell below its average cost. Counsel for Inglis conceded the point. Once it was established that Continental had to sell below average cost in order to sell at all, the statutory presumption disappeared. Once the statutory presumption disappeared, Inglis had no evidence that Continental was selling below cost for the purpose of injuring it.

108

Judge Canby's opinion says that Continental could have been sold at a price that was below cost but still higher than it did sell. This contention appears to be speculation.

109

There is a final defect with Inglis' claim. The presumption on which it relies does not come into effect simply by proof of sales below cost. The presumption comes into play only if sales below cost are joined "with proof of the injurious effect of such acts." Cal. Bus. & Prof.Code § 17071 (West 1987 & 1991 Supp.). In a market in which there was excess capacity no seller was going to be able to sell their bread except below cost. There has been no showing that the price Continental chose to sell at caused any injury to Inglis.

DAMAGES

110

On the foregoing analysis, the question of damages is not reached. However, as it has been reached by the court, the damages awarded Inglis must be considered. On this issue alone, Continental is entitled to judgment notwithstanding the verdict.

111

The Lost Profits. The E & W study, on which Inglis relied, showed that in the second quarter of 1970 Continental's price for private label bread was 3.1 cents above costs, averaged over a time span of up to seven years, that were not uniquely related to private label bread. As the time span that was used increased so did the number of costs that were thrown into the computation. There is no basis in the evidence for believing that the cost figures used by E & W correctly measured Continental's costs under California law.

112

Assuming, however, that in the second quarter of 1970 there was a 3.1 cent spread between these averaged costs and the price, E & W calculated what Continental would have charged for its private label bread if it had maintained the same spread from this period until early 1976. E & W then projected the profit that Inglis would have made had it too been able to sell bread at this hypothetical price. The result was a lost profits figure of $2 million. This methodology made all of Inglis' lost profits turn on a hypothetical price at which Continental could have sold its private label bread.

113

On appeal, Continental does not contend that Inglis, to prevail on this issue, must show that all of its losses were attributed to Continental's failure to sell at the hypothetical price. Continental's position is that for Inglis to recover any damages, it must show that these damages were specifically caused by Continental's alleged conduct. Inglis has failed to do so.

114

Among the causes of Inglis' repeated losses are the following:

115

1. Inglis' poor competitive position, emerging from a recent declaration of bankruptcy, failing to advertise, maintaining poor quality control of its product and holding a position in the industry so weak that the Quality Bakers Association, of which Inglis was a member, questioned in 1973 whether Inglis was "even needed in the market."

116

2. The dominant pricing role played by the captives of the grocery chains. All wholesalers had to meet the competition of the captives.

117

3. The competitive pricing of Campbell-Taggart, which was the largest wholesaler in the market.

118

4. The competitive pricing of American which, according to Inglis in 1972, engaged in "extreme predatory pricing."

119

In this highly competitive market it is simply nonsense to suppose that if Continental had maintained a certain price, Inglis would have been able to have maintained it too. Inglis' losses were clearly the result of a confluence of factors. Continental cannot be made responsible for damages which are not attributable to conduct which violated the antitrust laws. It is basic that the plaintiff "have suffered damages flowing directly from the violation of the Act." Weissensee v. Chronicle Publishing Co., 59 Cal.App.3d 723, 728, 129 Cal.Rptr. 188, 191 (1976). Inglis has failed to prove its lost profits were due to conduct of Continental.

120

The Going Concern Value. Inglis' expert testified that Inglis' going concern value was $3.6 million, a figure 31 times its hypothetical pre-tax earnings of $116,000 and 62 times Inglis' hypothetical after-tax earnings. On an after-tax basis a purchaser at this price would have had a return of 1.2 percent. To suppose that there would have been any purchasers at this price of this shaky company in a highly competitive market is contrary to the weight of the evidence and could not be a rational basis for the jury's verdict.

121

In addition, Inglis' expert's estimate made the assumption that Inglis would have increased its total sales of all bread products by 3.12 percent. This assumption flew in the face of Inglis' contention that the relevant market was the one pound private label and not the total white bread market. There is no reason to permit Inglis to prevail on one theory as to the market and to be awarded damages on a totally contradictory theory.

122

Finally, Judge Canby acknowledges that the expert picked a number out of the air in supposing that Inglis could have achieved a profit of 1.7 percent on sales. Judge Canby attempts to salvage this part of the damages claim using the more modest figure of .8 percent. But this court has no basis for substituting its own judgment for that of the expert. The expert picked an incredible figure. It should not be our task to salvage his credibility.

123

In sum, the expert's testimony as to valuation was against the weight of all the other evidence in the case and was based on an assumption as to the relevant market which, if consistently applied, would have undermined Inglis' basic case. There was, therefore, no evidence before the jury as to which it could rationally put a value on Inglis as a going concern. Inglis has proved no damages.

CONCLUSION

124

This case has dragged on for 20 years. It is apparently the only asset of a company that went out of existence 15 years ago--went out of existence because the quality of its products, the character of its marketing, and the management of its business made it unprofitable. In desperation it has tried to get something out of its bigger and more successful competitor. If we were to act on the theory that winners in an economic competition have to share the wealth with the losers, or that any defendant with a deep pocket should be made to disgorge for the benefit of an unhappy competitor, we could sustain the verdict which a jury, remarkably generous with other people's money, has awarded Inglis. The verdict is against the weight of the evidence on both federal claims; on the California claim; and as to the damages awarded. I would direct the entry of judgment for Continental.

1

In addition, Inglis brought two conspiracy claims against Continental; Inglis eventually dropped one and the district court awarded summary judgment to Continental on the second. Inglis' original Complaint also named two other defendants, American Bakeries Company and Campbell-Taggart Incorporated. At trial, the jury found American not liable. Campbell-Taggart settled the Inglis claims as part of a transaction in which Campbell-Taggart purchased Inglis' assets. As a result of its sale to Campbell-Taggart, Inglis ceased production and withdrew from the bread market. William Inglis & Sons Baking Co. v. ITT Continental Baking Co., 668 F.2d 1014, 1023-24 (9th Cir.1981), cert. denied, 459 U.S. 825, 103 S.Ct. 57, 58, 74 L.Ed.2d 61 (1982) (hereinafter "Inglis I ")

2

See note 1 supra

3

To prevail on this claim, Inglis needed to prove, in addition, that Continental engaged in anticompetitive conduct to accomplish its unlawful end, and that there was a dangerous probability that Continental would succeed in acquiring a monopoly. See Thurman at 1378; Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1027

4

We mean "production costs" to include expenses for distribution and marketing and any other expenses required to bring the bread to market

5

Inglis and E & W referred to this measure as the "average variable cost" of Continental's private label bread

6

To constitute sufficient evidence of intent, a price/cost comparison must employ a measure of cost that limits includable expenses to those that not only are "uniquely incurred," but also "vary with output" of the product alleged to have been sold at a predatory price. See Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1037. Step (ii) in Inglis' cost methodology shows that Inglis attempted to meet this second requirement. Because the cost computation was otherwise flawed, we do not reach the issue of whether the study correctly determined which expenses were variable

7

Inglis argues that the district court erred in excluding as inadmissible a report, prepared for Continental by McKinsey & Co., that advised Continental to "maintain prices to hasten wholesaler exit pace." Inglis argues that the court also erred by redacting Continental's own reports to remove references to "eliminat[ing competitors]" and "gear[ing] efforts toward market dominance." We express no opinion as to whether the district judge abused his discretion in ruling these items inadmissible because we find that even if admitted they would not have been sufficient evidence of specific intent. Without any evidence of Continental's reaction to McKinsey's recommendation, the report, while possibly relevant to the issue, could not establish Continental 's intent. The sales reports were equally inadequate because they contained no indication that Continental did, or should, seek to achieve its objectives by means of anticompetitive strategies. Even in the aggregate, this evidence was insufficient to prove specific intent to monopolize

8

Inglis argues that it was also entitled to demonstrate the necessary effect by showing a substantial possibility of injury to competition through market analysis. Our circuit has not yet accepted or rejected this alternative means of proving anticompetitive effect. See Inglis I, 668 F.2d at 1042 & n. 49. We decline to reach the question here because we find that Inglis' market analysis failed to show the substantial possibility of injury to competition

9

What Continental characterizes as Inglis' "admission" occurred during an extended argument over the significance of a damages exhibit. Both Inglis' expert witness and counsel stated that the intensity of market competition would have compelled Continental to price its private label bread below its average total cost. Inglis now argues that these statements were intended as part of the damages case only, and should have no relevance to liability. We do not reach this issue because we conclude that the alleged admission is irrelevant to the evidentiary burdens established by the California statute

10

The rationality or wisdom of § 17071 as applied to "normal" market conditions, in which sellers are able to sell at or above total cost, is not at issue here. We accept, for purposes of this appeal, the soundness of § 17071's evidentiary presumption under those circumstances, and concern ourselves only with whether the particular market condition identified by Continental renders the presumption irrational in that application

11

With respect to the fourth quarter of 1970, for example, Inglis alleged that Continental's average total cost was 22cents, that the market would have allowed sales at a price somewhere between 18.2cents and 22cents, and that Continental sold at 18cents. See Plaintiff's Exhibit 501 and Transcript at 1852-54

12

Continental also argues that § 17071 conflicts with federal law by allowing a jury to condemn a price below average total cost where it was not possible to obtain a higher price. We need not reach this issue, however, because this case does not present that scenario. Inglis admitted only that the market would not have permitted Continental to sell at or above average total cost; it did not admit--and expressly denied--that the market would not have allowed Continental to sell at a price higher than the price Continental actually charged

13

Continental bases its argument here entirely on federal law. This fact may indicate that Continental does not intend to challenge the causation element of the state law claim, in which case there is no need for us to consider it. Alternatively, Continental may intend for this argument to apply to the state claim, thus impliedly contending that state standards on causation are identical to federal standards. Granting Continental the benefit of the doubt, we construe the argument in the second way. We thus assume arguendo that the federal standard applies, and reject Continental's challenge because Inglis satisfied the federal standard for causation

14

Continental intimated at trial, for example, that during particular periods between 1970 and 1976 Inglis may have suffered a loss in profits regardless of Continental's pricing. See Transcript at 1912-13

15

McGlinchy v. Shell Chemical Co., 845 F.2d 802 (9th Cir.1988), does not support Continental's theory on causation. In McGlinchy, we upheld the district court's decision to exclude the plaintiff's evidence on damages because it failed to meet the standard for competent evidence as to any of the claimed injury. Among the several serious flaws in the McGlinchy evidence that distinguish it from Inglis' evidence in this case are the following: failure to relate asserted lost profits to any specific acts by the defendants; concession that the decline in sales, which was responsible for lost profits, could have been caused by "anything"; failure to state which particular lines of plaintiff's business had suffered declining sales, even though plaintiff's theory was that defendant's unlawful conduct had affected particular lines. 845 F.2d at 806-07

16

E & W used the measure it called "average variable cost". See note 4 and accompanying text supra

17

Continental claims that it was wrong to include the entire period from late 1970 to early 1976 in this calculation, arguing that not every price charged by Continental through this period was unlawful, and citing E & W's own data showing that there were occasions when Continental priced above cost. However, the particular data to which Continental refers involves only what E & W called "average variable cost." With respect to liability on the state claim, only average total cost is relevant; and E & W's study showed that Continental's prices were below that measure throughout the entire period involved

18

Continental also introduced evidence that federal price controls were implemented during the liability period, but Inglis countered with evidence that Continental could have sought relief from price controls. The jury could have accepted Inglis' theory that price controls were not a substantial factor in pricing during the liability period

19

Our conclusion that the evidence was insufficient to support use of the base period figures makes it unnecessary to address two further arguments Continental offers against Inglis' calculation of lost profits: (1) that it was improper to assume that, if Continental had increased its price, others would have followed, and (2) that it was improper to assume that, if prices had been increased, the quantity sold would not have declined

20

With respect to the state claim, the district court and we sit in diversity and must base decisions affecting postjudgment interest on state law. See Michael-Regan Co., Inc. v. Lindell, 527 F.2d 653, 659 (9th Cir.1975)

21

See note 1 supra

22

Inglis' cross-appeal challenges the amount of the deduction resulting from the Campbell-Taggart settlement. We deal with that question in Section III, C, infra. We are concerned here only with the question whether the deduction should be made before or after trebling of the damages

23

See section I supra

24

Inglis bases its argument here entirely on federal law. This fact may indicate that Inglis does not intend to challenge the causation element of the state law claim, in which case we need not consider the issue. Alternatively, Inglis may intend for this argument to apply to the state claim, thus impliedly contending that the state approach to interest accrual is identical to the federal approach. Granting Inglis the benefit of the doubt, we construe the argument in the second way. We therefore assume arguendo that the federal approach applies, and reject Inglis' challenge because the court acted consistently with federal law by awarding interest only from the date of judgment on the second trial's verdicts