874 F2d 1417 Palmer v. Brg of Georgia Inc Bar/bri

874 F.2d 1417

57 USLW 2747, 1989-1 Trade Cases 68,612,
13 Fed.R.Serv.3d 1043

Jay PALMER, et al., Plaintiffs-Appellants,
v.
BRG OF GEORGIA, INC., a Georgia Corporation, d/b/a BAR/BRI,
et al., Defendants-Appellees.

No. 87-8804.

United States Court of Appeals,
Eleventh Circuit.

June 7, 1989.
As Amended on Denial of Rehearing and Rehearing In Banc Jan.
29, 1990.*

John C. Butters, Atlanta, Ga. and James Ponsoldt, Athens, Ga., for plaintiffs-appellants.

Trammell Newton, Hansell & Post and Kevin E. Grady, Alston & Bird, Atlanta, Ga., for defendants-appellees.

Appeal from the United States District Court For the Northern District of Georgia.

Before HATCHETT and CLARK, Circuit Judges, and FITZPATRICK*, District Judge.

HATCHETT, Circuit Judge:

1

In this action brought by former law students of the University of Georgia Law School against bar review companies, we affirm the district court's ruling that the bar review companies did not violate the Sherman Act.

FACTS

2

Appellants, all 1985 graduates of the University of Georgia Law School in Athens, Georgia, brought this antitrust action against BRG of Georgia, Inc. (BRG), a Georgia corporation, Ronald O. Pelletier, BRG's owner, and Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Legal and Professional Publications, Inc. (HBJ), a Delaware corporation.1 The appellants took a bar review course offered by BRG during January and February of 1985 in preparation for the Georgia bar examination.

3

In 1979, BRG offered a bar review course which covered the federal multi-state and Georgia law components of the Georgia bar exam. The BRG course included written materials plus lawyers and professors' live and videotaped lectures. In 1979, BRG used West Publishing Company's (West) free standardized multi-state materials which were being test marketed. BRG offered its bar review course at a lower price than it would have charged otherwise due to the availability of the free multi-state materials.

4

In 1973, HBJ began offering a review course for the Georgia bar exam and has offered bar review courses and materials nationwide under the trade name "Bar/Bri." The record does not contain a precise description of HBJ's Georgia course, but the parties state that it is similar to the format of the BRG course. HBJ developed its own standardized multi-state materials and sold these as a part of its Georgia course.

5

In 1979, BRG and HBJ competed in Georgia. In response to the low price of BRG's course, HBJ reduced the price of its Georgia course and lost money as a result. Richard Conviser, chairman of HBJ's board of directors, states in his affidavit that HBJ lost $45,000 on revenues of $120,000 without accounting for overhead.

6

At some point in 1979, West informed BRG that it planned to sell its multi-state materials through book stores, thus ending the test market arrangement. At about the same time, the lawyer who had been in charge of conducting HBJ's Georgia course suffered a heart attack. Conviser's affidavit states that HBJ decided to withdraw from the Georgia market at this time, but no documentation of this decision has been offered.

7

Conviser met with Pelletier in early 1980. On April 22, 1980, BRG and HBJ entered into a written agreement which gave BRG an exclusive license to use HBJ's name "Bar/Bri" in Georgia. HBJ agreed that it would no longer offer a bar review course in Georgia and that it would not compete with BRG in Georgia. BRG agreed not to compete with HBJ outside of Georgia.

8

Immediately after execution of the 1980 agreement, the price of BRG's course rose from $150 to over $400. The record does not disclose what prices HBJ or other companies were charging for similar bar review courses. In February, 1982, a group of Georgia law students brought a class action lawsuit against BRG and HBJ alleging identical antitrust violations as are alleged in this case. See Edwards, et al. v. BRG of Georgia, Inc., et al., Middle District of Georgia, Circuit A, No. 82-13-Ath. The class included those students taking BRG's course between April 22, 1980 and June 15, 1984. By offering partial refunds to the class members, BRG and HBJ settled that class.

9

During the pendency of the 1982 class action, BRG and HBJ executed a modified agreement. In this modified agreement, HBJ withdrew BRG's exclusive right to market HBJ's multi-state materials in Georgia. However, BRG retained the exclusive right to use "Bar/Bri" in connection with its course. Also, the modified agreement dropped the express covenant not to compete which had been contained in the initial agreement. Since the execution of the 1982 agreement, HBJ has not competed with BRG in Georgia nor licensed its multi-state materials for use by any other Georgia bar review course.

10

In 1979, the majority of University of Georgia law students who used a bar review course conducted in Athens, Georgia, took either the HBJ or the BRG courses. The record contains no similar data for subsequent years. The BRG course is currently marketed statewide, and is conducted at various locations in Georgia, including Athens and Atlanta. Other bar review courses are offered to Georgia bar applicants, namely, the "NORD" and "PMBR" courses, but these are not described in the record.

PROCEDURAL HISTORY

11

The appellants sought to represent a class consisting of those law students who attended a BRG course in Athens, Georgia, between June 15, 1984, and the present. Counts I through IV each alleges section 1 violations of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.A. Sec. 1.2 A different theory of per se liability was advanced under each of these counts, namely, price-fixing cartel (Count I); market and customer allocation (Count II); boycott and concerted refusal to deal (Count III); and unreasonable joint venture (Count IV).3 Counts V through IX of the complaint each alleged section 2 violations of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.A. Sec. 2.4 The allegations were: conspiracy to monopolize in Georgia (Count V); attempt to monopolize in Georgia (Count VI); monopoly in Georgia (Count VII); conspiracy to monopolize nationwide (Count VIII); and attempt to monopolize nationwide (Count IX).

12

BRG and HBJ answered denying liability and denying that the class described by the appellants could be properly certified. On February 7, 1986, appellants moved for class certification and later moved for partial summary judgment on one of the conspiracy counts of their complaint. On May 2, 1986, BRG and HBJ moved for summary judgment. Appellants subsequently filed a motion for Fed.R.Civ.P. 11 sanctions against Pelletier.

13

On January 9, 1987, the district court denied appellants' motion for summary judgment, but granted BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment as to Counts II through IX of the complaint, and deferred ruling on Count I. The district court found that BRG Publications, Inc. and Bar Review Group, Inc. were related corporations which have been defunct at relevant times and had no involvement in any allegedly anti-competitive activities. The district court granted summary judgment to BRG Publications, Inc. and Bar Review Group on all counts. In separate orders, the district court also denied appellants' motions for class certification and Rule 11 sanctions.

14

On February 9, 1987, appellants filed a Motion for Reconsideration of the January 9 rulings, and a memorandum responding to the district court's invitation to produce evidence to support a section 1 "rule of reason violation" of the Sherman Act. The district court declined to reconsider its previous rulings, held that the appellants had failed to support a rule of reason violation, and granted BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment on Count I. On July 16, 1987, the district court entered judgment. Appellants filed a motion to alter or amend the judgment, and the district court denied that motion. Appellants then filed a timely notice of appeal.

ISSUES

15

The appellants raise five issues on appeal:

16

1) whether the district court's determination that the appellants "may lack financial commitment" to this consumer class action constitutes a proper legal standard;

17

2) whether the district court abused its discretion in denying a motion for sanctions against Pelletier;

18

3) whether the district court erred in granting BRG and HBJ summary judgment;

19

4) whether evidence that BRG's and HBJ's combination enabled them to: increase price 800-percent; reduce output; and eliminate consumer choice for a product uniformly perceived to be indispensable, is sufficient proof of anticompetitive effect to preclude summary judgment under section 2 of the Sherman Act; and

20

5) whether the district court erred in granting BRG and HBJ summary judgment when the appellants produced sufficient probative evidence from which a jury could have reasonably inferred that any relevant product and geographic market existed; monopoly power existed or was dangerously likely to exist in that claimed market; and that BRG and HBJ took actions to secure or intended to secure such monopoly power as required for appellants to establish a violation of section 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act.

DISCUSSION

I. Consumer Class Certification

21

The appellants contend that the district court applied an erroneous legal standard in applying Fed.R.Civ.P. 23(a)(4) and misread the record in denying their motion for class certification. Citing Kirkpatrick, et al. v. Bradford, et al., 827 F.2d 718 (11th Cir.1987), the appellants argue that consumer class certification should not be denied because of a lack of subjective interest on the part of the named plaintiffs, unless their participation is so minimal that they virtually have abdicated the conduct of their case to their lawyer.

22

BRG and HBJ cite Kirkpatrick to argue that the adequacy of class representation under Fed.R.Civ.P. 23(a) is primarily a factual issue best left for the district court's determination. They argue that the trial court's denial of certification should be upheld absent an abuse of discretion. BRG and HBJ further argue that the individual appellants had little knowledge of the class action when deposed, and that the named appellants were unaware of the extent of their obligation to pay expenses. Thus, BRG and HBJ assert that the record demonstrates the appellants' lack of involvement and unwillingness to finance the case.

23

Whether a lawsuit may proceed as a class action is committed to the sound discretion of the district court, and its determination will not be overturned absent a showing that it has abused its discretion. In re Dennis Greenman Securities Litigation, 829 F.2d 1539, 1543-44 (11th Cir.1987). The general rule provides that the district court's class certification is final unless an abuse of discretion exists, or the court has applied impermissible legal criteria or standards. Lawler v. Alexander, 698 F.2d 439, 441 (11th Cir.1983).

The district court held:

24

At this juncture, plaintiffs only state that they are only capable of assuming the cost of mailing notice to approximately 280 absent class members.

25

Rule 23(a), Fed.R.Civ.P. requires that parties seeking to represent a class demonstrate that they will adequately protect the interest of the class. Because plaintiffs may lack financial commitment sufficient for adequate investigation and trial preparation in light of the court's ruling, the court finds that certification of the class would be improper at this juncture. Accordingly, the motion for class certification is hereby denied.

26

We hold that the district court did not abuse its discretion, nor apply impermissible legal criteria or standards in denying the appellants' request for class certification. At the point where certification became important, the district court had granted BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment on all counts except one. The district court allowed the appellants thirty days to establish a rule of reason claim under Count I, because it had rejected their claims on per se liability. The district court properly exercised its discretion in denying the class certification because the court expected the rule of reason development to require a greater degree of financial commitment than the appellants' depositions reflected they possessed. Accordingly, the district court's denial of consumer class certification is affirmed.

II. Fed.R.Civ.P. 11 Sanctions

27

The appellants established that Pelletier submitted a false affidavit. BRG and HBJ first entered into a licensing agreement in April, 1980. Paragraph 27 of that agreement provided:

28

Because HBJ is providing its skill, expertise and special methods to Pelletier and BRG, if either Pelletier or BRG desires to conduct a bar review examination course in any state other than Georgia, it shall first offer HBJ the opportunity to license its courses and materials on the same terms and conditions as contained herein. Because HBJ or its licensees already conduct courses in certain states, BRG and Pelletier agree: (1) not to request a license from HBJ for such states; and (2) they will not directly or indirectly own, manage, operate, join, invest, control or participate in or be connected as an officer, employee, partner, director, independent contractor or otherwise, with any business which is operating or participating in the preparation of candidates in a state in which HBJ or its licensee is then operating a bar examination review course. Those certain states in which HBJ or its licensees are presently operating is attached hereto as Exhibit "A".

29

Mr. Pelletier's affidavit states in paragraphs 3:

30

At no time have I ever agreed with Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Legal Publications, Inc. ("HBJ Legal"), or Richard Conviser, or any agent or employee of HBJ Legal concerning:

31

a) the prices BRG would charge for bar review courses;

32

b) where BRG would offer courses or not offer courses; or

33

c) hiring only lecturers made available by HBJ Legal.

34

The appellants argued that Pelletier committed perjury in paragraph 3(b) of his affidavit and thereby violated Fed.R.Civ.P. 115, warranting sanctions. The district court found that the alleged inconsistency between the two statements did not establish perjury, and denied the motion for sanctions.

35

The appellants contend that Rule 11 sanctions are mandatory, not discretionary. BRG and HBJ contend that the district court properly denied the appellants' motion for sanctions and correctly ruled that no evidence in the record established that Pelletier had committed perjury. BRG and HBJ further argue that the district court did not abuse its discretion in denying the appellants' Rule 11 motion for sanctions.

36

Although the district court found that Pelletier submitted a false affidavit, the district court did not impose Rule 11 sanctions because it could not determine whether Pelletier was guilty of perjury, that is, whether his untrue statements were intentional. In reviewing the record, we find that the district court did not abuse its discretion in denying the appellants' motion for Rule 11 sanctions. See Donaldson v. Clark, 819 F.2d 1551 (11th Cir.1987). Accordingly, we affirm the district court's denial of Rule 11 sanctions.

III. Summary Judgment on Antitrust Claims

A. Standard of Review

37

Appellate review of the granting of a motion for summary judgment questions whether any genuine issue of material fact exists. Fed.R.Civ.P. 56(c). When reviewing a summary judgment decision, the reviewing court is bound by the same legal standards as those that control the district court in determining whether summary judgment is appropriate. Amey Inc. v. Gulf Abstract & Title, Inc., 758 F.2d 1486, 1502 (11th Cir.1985), cert. denied, 475 U.S. 1107, 106 S.Ct. 1513, 89 L.Ed.2d 912 (1986).

38

To survive BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment, the appellants must establish a genuine issue of material fact as to whether BRG and HBJ entered into an illegal conspiracy that caused the appellants to suffer a cognizable injury. Fed.R.Civ.P. 56(e). This showing has two components: first, the appellants must show more than a conspiracy in violation of the antitrust laws existed; they must show an injury to them resulting from the illegal conduct; second, the issue of fact must be genuine. Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 585-86, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 1355-56, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986); Fed.R.Civ.P. 56(c), (e).

39

When BRG and HBJ carry their burden under Fed.R.Civ.P. 56(c), the appellants must do more than simply show some metaphysical doubt as to the material facts. The appellants must come forward with specific facts demonstrating a genuine issue for trial. Rule 56(e). Where the record, taken as a whole, does not lead a rational trier of fact to find for the appellants, no genuine issue for trial exists. Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 586-87, 106 S.Ct. at 1356; Dunnivant v. Bi-State Auto Parts, 851 F.2d 1575, 1579-80 (11th Cir.1988).

40

In reviewing a grant of summary judgment, the inferences to be drawn from the underlying facts must be viewed in the light most favorable to the non-moving party. But antitrust law limits the range of permissible inferences from ambiguous evidence in a Sherman Act section 1 case. Conduct as consistent with permissible competition as well as illegal conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an inference of antitrust conspiracy. Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 587-88, 106 S.Ct. at 1356-57; Dunnivant, 851 F.2d at 1579-80.

41

To survive BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment, the appellants must present evidence tending to exclude the possibility that BRG and HBJ acted independently. The appellants must demonstrate that the inference of conspiracy is reasonable in light of the competing inferences of independent action or collusive action that could not have harmed them. Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 588, 106 S.Ct. at 1357; Dunnivant, 851 F.2d at 1579-80.

42

In evaluating the appellants' per se liability claims under section 1 of the Sherman Act, the district court found that generally, a plaintiff asserting a section 1 claim must prove that the defendant's acts or conduct had an anti-competitive effect in relevant geographic and product markets. See Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 69 S.Ct. 1051, 93 L.Ed. 1371 (1949). Thus, the appellants bore the burden of proof and were required to make a factual showing in support of these elements when BRG and HBJ moved for summary judgment. See Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, 477 U.S. 317, 106 S.Ct. 2548, 91 L.Ed.2d 265 (1986).

43

The district court observed that where a defendant's complained of acts and conduct fit certain judicially recognized categories, the plaintiffs need not establish that the defendants' conduct actually had an anti-competitive effect, nor establish the relevant product or geographic markets. Thus, the defendant is per se liable for any damages suffered by the plaintiff. The rationale is that the designated conduct is so inherently and reliably anti-competitive that its anti-competitive effects may be presumed.

B. Sherman Act Sec. 1 Analysis

1. Per Se Violation

44

Certain categories of concerted action which violate section 1 of the Sherman Act have been held to be per se illegal. Per se rules are appropriate only for conduct that is manifestly anti-competitive, that is, conduct that would almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output. See Business Electronics Corporation v. Sharp Electronics Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 108 S.Ct. 1515, 1519, 99 L.Ed.2d 808 cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 108 S.Ct. 1727, 100 L.Ed.2d 192 (1988). See also FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458-59, 106 S.Ct. 2009, 2017-18, 90 L.Ed.2d 445 (1986) (the Court has "been slow ... to extend per se analysis to restraints imposed in the context of business relationships where the economic impact of certain practices is not immediately obvious."); NCAA v. Board of Regents of University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 103-04, 104 S.Ct. 2948, 2961, 82 L.Ed.2d 70 (1984) ("Per se rules are invoked when surrounding circumstances make the likelihood of anti-competitive conduct so great as to render unjustified further examination of the challenged conduct."); and National Society of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692, 98 S.Ct. 1355, 1365, 55 L.Ed.2d 637 (1978) (agreements are per se illegal only if their "nature and necessary effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their illegality").

45

The appellants contend that the district court erred in denying their motion for partial summary judgment based upon theories of per se liability under section 1 of the Sherman Act. The appellants argue that the existence of an agreement between HBJ and BRG providing for the withdrawal of HBJ from an existing market and its refusal to bid for customers in that market (Georgia), in exchange for the agreement that BRG not sell in other markets or bid for customers in other markets, constitutes per se illegal market allocation and bid rigging. The appellants argue that the district court erroneously held this agreement not to constitute a per se illegal market or customer allocation agreement. The appellants further argue that an agreement between competitors to eliminate price competition and preclude future competition through the exchange of mutual covenants not to compete, coupled with a provision to share profits, constitutes per se illegal price fixing.

46

The appellants further argue that the district court's holding that BRG's and HBJ's conduct does not constitute per se illegal price fixing because neither BRG nor HBJ agreed upon the price each would continue to charge for its product is erroneous. According to appellants, BRG's and HBJ's conduct is precisely the kind of combination to which the per se rule is intended to apply.

47

BRG and HBJ contend that the district court properly granted summary judgment because of the appellants' failure to present significant probative evidence indicating a violation of the antitrust laws. BRG and HBJ assert that they were in a vertical supplier-retailer relationship at the time of the first license agreement; had executed a second agreement; and have submitted affidavits that they were free to compete with each other.

48

The appellants seek to denominate the agreements and dealings between BRG and HBJ as arrangements of the type to which per se liability has been recognized, namely, price fixing, United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 60 S.Ct. 811, 84 L.Ed. 1129 (1940); market and customer allocation, United States v. Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 92 S.Ct. 1126, 31 L.Ed.2d 515 (1972); boycott and concerted refusal to deal, Fashion Originators' Guild of America v. Federal Trade Commission, 312 U.S. 457, 61 S.Ct. 703, 85 L.Ed. 949 (1941); and unreasonable joint venture, Citizens Publishing Co. v. United States, 394 U.S. 131, 89 S.Ct. 927, 22 L.Ed.2d 148 (1969).

49

We agree with the district court that the modified agreement (1982) is not a market allocation agreement to which per se liability applies. First, the agreement is not a "naked agreement" between competitors to allocate the market. Second, HBJ and BRG are not horizontal competitors. HBJ's affidavit states that it is no longer a competitor in the Georgia market. The appellees have failed to produce evidence to the contrary. In the absence of evidence other than the affidavit on this issue, we cannot conclude that HBJ is doing business in Georgia.

50

The district court found that the arrangement between BRG and HBJ did not fit within any recognized category of per se liability. The district court further found that the 1982 agreement was not a classic form of price fixing where two competitors agreed what price they would charge for their products. On the contrary, the district court found that neither the 1980 nor the 1982 agreement explicitly addressed the factor of price, and that HBJ has never had any right under either agreement to be consulted about the price of the BRG course. See Socony-Vacuum Oil Co. 310 U.S. 150, 60 S.Ct. 811. The district court also found that although the agreement of two competitors to "pool" their products may exert an upward influence of price, such an agreement is not inherently anti-competitive.

51

The district court found that neither agreement between BRG and HBJ constituted the kind of market or customer allocation agreement which has been recognized as a basis for per se liability. See Topco, 405 U.S. 596, 92 S.Ct. 1126. The district court found that this was not a situation where competitors divided up a market in which both were doing business, each taking a portion of the market. The district court also found that BRG had never done business outside the state of Georgia, that nothing in the record suggested that it ever intended to do so, and that HBJ has done business nationwide, but withdrew from the Georgia market following the 1980 agreement between BRG and HBJ. Thus, the district court found the only market ever claimed by both defendants was the state of Georgia, which was not divided up under either the 1980 or 1982 agreements.

52

The district court ruled that BRG's and HBJ's conduct did not constitute a boycott or concerted refusal to deal. See Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 89 S.Ct. 1562, 23 L.Ed.2d 129 (1969). The district court rejected the appellants' attempt to invoke the per se theory based on the fact that the agreement prohibited BRG from hiring certain law lecturers because the appellants had no standing to raise that argument.

53

Finally, the district court found that the conduct described in the record differed from that recognized in Citizens Publishing Co., 394 U.S. 131, 89 S.Ct. 927, as an unreasonable joint venture which was per se illegal. The district court found that BRG and HBJ did not pool capital, and HBJ had no risk of loss on the Georgia bar review course. Thus, the arrangement created was not a joint venture, and the Citizens Publishing theory is inapplicable.

54

The district court denied the appellants' motion for partial summary judgment and granted summary judgment to the defendants on Counts II through IV. The district court's analyses of these issues are thorough and legally sound. Accordingly, we affirm the district court's ruling that the appellants failed to establish per se liability under section 1 of the Sherman Act.

2. The Rule of Reason Violation

55

Because no theory of per se liability applied to the appellants' claims under section 1 of the Sherman Act, the appellants may only prevail by demonstrating that BRG's and HBJ's arrangement had an anti-competitive effect in relevant geographic and product markets. Whether the action violates section 1 of the Sherman Act is determined through case-by-case application of the rule of reason when the action is not per se illegal; the fact-finder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition. Business Electronics, 108 S.Ct. at 1519.

56

The district court required the appellants to submit significant probative evidence that the 1980 agreement between BRG and HBJ, as modified in 1982, had an anti-competitive effect in relevant product and geographic markets. As evidence of anti-competitive effect, the appellants offered the contract itself, the fact that the price went up after the parties signed the contract, and the affidavit of Leon Van Gelderen, a Georgia State School of Law graduate.

57

The appellants relied on an affidavit of Dr. William Henry, filed February 9, 1987, to address the issues of relevant product market and relevant geographic market. This affidavit stated that the relevant market is "comprehensive bar review courses that prepare students to take the Georgia bar examination" and that the relevant geographic market was "Athens, Georgia, during the winter academic term of law school."

58

The appellants contend that BRG's and HBJ's 1982 contract modification and subsequent pricing and noncompetitive conduct are evidence of a continuing horizontal conspiracy. The appellants argue that no material facts are genuinely disputed regarding Counts I and II of the complaint (price fixing and market allocation). They contest the district court's denial of their motion for partial summary judgment on liability for those counts. The appellants argue that the district court erroneously applied structural and temporal tests in granting BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment on the appellants' section 1 rule of reason theory. The appellants further contend that their evidence was sufficient to create reasonably conflicting inferences regarding the unreasonableness of BRG's and HBJ's conduct.

59

BRG and HBJ contend that the appellants failed to show any basis for a section 1 rule of reason violation. They argue that the appellants' rule of reason analysis suffers from its failure to specify exactly which agreement was unreasonable. BRG and HBJ contend that no significant probative evidence exists in the record from which a jury could reasonably infer that an unwritten agreement existed between BRG and HBJ not to compete against each other in selling bar review courses. BRG and HBJ argue that if the appellants are relying on this unwritten agreement, then the rule of reason analysis ends because no agreement exists to be evaluated.

60

The second possible agreement upon which the appellants may have relied was the license agreement between HBJ and BRG when the appellants took their bar review courses. In this agreement, HBJ promised to supply bar review materials to BRG on a nonexclusive basis. The district court found that the license agreement did not contain any anti-competitive provisions. Thus, BRG and HBJ contend that the appellants' failure to prove the existence of an appropriate geographic and product market in which the effects of HBJ's agreement with BRG could be evaluated defeated their rule of reason claim.

61

In analyzing the appellants' rule of reason claim, the district court examined whether the appellants offered significant probative evidence that BRG's and HBJ's 1980 agreement as modified in 1982 had an anti-competitive effect in relevant geographic and product markets. The district court found that the possibility of anti-competitive effect existed in the contract between BRG and HBJ, which was amended in 1982, to make BRG's license nonexclusive and to delete the covenants not to compete, but that such effect cannot be presumed from the contract itself. The district court found that although the price of BRG's course went up significantly after the 1980 contract signing, this fact did not suffice to demonstrate anti-competitive effect, especially when the price increase came on the heels of West's withdrawal of the free multi-state materials. The district court found that it was as safe to assume that the price increase reflected these additional costs as it was to assume that the higher prices were merely to gouge the customer. The district court found that the affidavit of Van Gelderen did not add significant evidence on the issue of anti-competitive effect.

62

Finding flaws in Dr. Henry's affidavit, the district court determined that it was not a substitute for expert product market analysis, and that the anti-competitive effect of the contract was more appropriately measured in a statewide market. The district court also ruled that "Athens, Georgia, during the winter academic term of law school" was not a relevant geographic market. The district court found that no significant probative evidence established that the modified contractual arrangement had a present anti-competitive effect in a relevant product and geographic market. Accordingly, the court granted BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment on Count I. In reviewing the district court analysis, we affirm.

C. Sherman Act Sec. 2 Analysis

63

In addressing Count V, conspiracy to monopolize in Georgia; Count VI, attempt to monopolize in Georgia; and Count VII, monopoly in Georgia, the district court examined the appellants' evidence of relevant product and geographic markets and monopoly power or dangerous probability of monopoly. This circuit has held that "proof of relevant product and geographic market is absolutely essential to appellants' Section 2 claims." American Key Corp. v. Cole Nat. Corp, 762 F.2d 1569, 1579 (11th Cir.1985). Further, to prove an attempt to monopolize (Count VI), an antitrust plaintiff must prove the existence of "methods, means and practices which would, if successful, accomplish monopolization, and which, though falling short, nevertheless approach so close as to create a dangerous probability of it...." American Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 785, 814-15, 66 S.Ct. 1125, 1127, 1141-42, 90 L.Ed. 1575 (1946). To prove a claim of monopoly (Count VII), an antitrust plaintiff must prove monopoly power in the relevant market, that is, the power to control prices or exclude competition. United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 571, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 1704, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966).

64

The appellants contend that they did not have to prove that BRG's and HBJ's combination had an anti-competitive effect in a specifically defined product and geographic market, nor that a particular written contract has a present anti-competitive effect in order to establish the section 2 violation. The appellants argue that the structural standards for proof of unreasonableness contained in both the district court's January 9 and July 8 orders are wrong for three reasons: (1) that proof of specific product and geographic markets is not required in a horizontal rule of reason case to prove anti-competitive effect; (2) the evidence of an anti-competitive purpose alone, even without anti-competitive effects, would prove unreasonableness; and (3) evidence that prices were intended to and did "skyrocket," output was reduced, and consumer choice eliminated is sufficient to prove a rule of reason violation.

65

Because the district court found that the appellants presented no significant probative evidence that the modified contractual arrangement between BRG and HBJ had a present anti-competitive effect in a relevant product and geographic market, the appellants have no foundation for a section 2 claim. Even so, the appellants argue that evidence of an 800-percent price increase without loss of sales or new entry, two market surveys and unopposed expert opinion showing that defendants control at least 93-percent of any relevant market, and a reduction in output and elimination of consumer choice are sufficient to prove an anti-competitive effect in a relevant product and geographic market. The appellants argue that the district court transformed their rule of reason claim into a section 2 structural claim and then arbitrarily refused to acknowledge or consider their structural evidence.

66

The appellants further argue that the district court's conceptions of product market definition, geographic market definition, and anti-competitive effect are contrary to precedent. They assert that the court misread the complaint in reference to their charge of statewide market allocation, ignored a deposition, market survey, and BRG's and HBJ's enrollment contracts demonstrating increasing price without loss of sales statewide, and gave insufficient weight to other affidavits. The appellants also argue that BRG's and HBJ's product is perceived as unique by consumers, its price is significantly higher than theoretical alternatives, and it has the distinctive properties and discreet vendors. They assert that every criteria for product market identification cited in Brown Shoe v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962) is satisfied by the record in this case. Thus, the appellants contend that BRG and HBJ took actions to secure, or intended to secure monopoly power in violation of section 2 of the Sherman Act.

67

BRG and HBJ argue that the authorities cited by the appellants have little to do with the kind, quantum, or quality of proof that a plaintiff must offer to show that an agreement in place between BRG and HBJ in 1985 violated the rule of reason. BRG and HBJ argue that the appellants are simply wrong in suggesting that a restraint which is not per se illegal does not need to be evaluated within the context of a defined product and geographic market. BRG and HBJ contend that appellants' failure to establish the existence of a relevant product and geographic market thus defeats their section 2 claims.

68

BRG and HBJ argue that the appellants failed to produce sufficient evidence to avoid summary judgment on their theories with respect to monopolization of alleged Georgia markets. BRG and HBJ contend that the appellants failed to establish the structural elements of the relevant product or geographic market. BRG and HBJ further contend that the section 2 offenses of conspiracy, attempt, and actual monopolization all require the same proof with respect to the structural attributes of the economic market in which the violations are alleged to have taken place. To prevail, BRG and HBJ argue that the appellants must show: (1) the existence of some economically meaningful market, defined by its product and geographic characteristics, and (2) the existence of monopoly power within the identified market. BRG and HBJ argue that the appellants failed on both accounts. Because the appellants failed to establish any significant probative evidence of conspiracy or agreement, BRG and HBJ contend that all section 2 theories must fail. Also, BRG and HBJ contend that no significant probative evidence has been produced from which a jury could reasonably infer that BRG and HBJ were parties in 1985 to an agreement to give BRG control over any Georgia market.

69

The district court held that proof of the relevant geographic and product market is essential to all section 2 claims. The district court found Dr. Henry's affidavit to be insufficient to identify or justify a proper product or geographic market. The district court also found that the entirety of the appellants' effort to identify proper product and geographic markets was contained in the affidavit of Dr. William Henry, filed in opposition to BRG's and HBJ's motion for summary judgment.6 The districtcourt held Dr. Henry's affidavit insufficient to define the relevant product market. Particularly, because Dr. Henry chose to define the product market in such a narrow and seemingly artificial manner, the district court found that the lack of justification for his conclusions rendered it valueless. The district court held the relevant geographic market to be the geographic area of "effective competition" for the product in question. American Key Corp., 762 F.2d at 1581.

70

Although the appellants' failure to properly identify relevant product and geographic markets required the district court to grant summary judgment to BRG and HBJ on Counts V through VII, the district court found that Count VI (attempt to monopolize in Georgia) and Count VII (monopoly in Georgia) would have failed for additional reasons. Count VI would have failed under the American Tobacco requirement, and Count VII would have failed under the Grinnell requirement. See supra p. 1426. The district court found that the appellants' only effort to show evidence of these requirements was the conclusory statements of the appellants that they had "no other choice" than the BRG course when they took it in January through February, 1984 in Athens, and the statement in Dr. Henry's first affidavit that "[f]urther, Ronald Pelletier testified that defendants accounted for at least eighty percent of the sales of bar review courses in the Athens area." The district court found that these assertions were "clearly insufficient."

CONCLUSION

71

Because of the district court's thorough, complete, and correct antitrust analysis regarding the appellants' claims and BRG's and HBJ's motions for summary judgment, we affirm.

72

AFFIRMED.

CLARK, Circuit Judge, dissenting:

73

The majority concludes that the district court's analysis of the procedural and substantive antitrust issues in this case is "thorough, complete, and correct." I dissent.1

I. Facts

74

The facts in this appeal are relatively simple. From 1976 to the present, defendants BRG of Georgia (BRG) and its owner Ronald Pelletier have offered a comprehensive bar review course in Georgia.2 The course reviews both the multistate and Georgia portions of the Georgia bar exam through written materials and live and videotaped lectures by attorneys and law professors. During 1979, BRG was utilizing free multistate materials that West Publishing Company was test marketing.

75

Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Legal and Professional Publications (HBJ) sells comprehensive bar review courses in forty states and is the largest provider of bar review materials and lecture services in the country.3 HBJ produces and uses its own multistate materials. HBJ began offering a Georgia review on a limited basis in 1976. During the period 1977-79, BRG competed directly with HBJ in the provision of comprehensive bar review courses in Georgia.4 BRG and HBJ were the two dominant providers of bar review courses in Georgia at this time.

76

Beginning in 1979, BRG conducted an intensive advertising campaign against HBJ which HBJ alleges included false representations about the HBJ course. Vigorous price competition between BRG and HBJ resulted in driving the price of their bar review courses into the range of about $150 per student. The rivalry between BRG and HBJ was rancorous and vitriolic. Each accused the other of engaging in illegal tactics. According to Richard Conviser, head of HBJ's Legal and Professional Publications, HBJ incurred a loss of $45,000 on revenues of $120,000 in the 1979 price war. At some point during 1979, West Publishing decided to begin selling its multistate materials in bookstores; West therefore decided to charge BRG for the formerly free multistate materials.

77

Conviser asserts that HBJ unilaterally decided to withdraw from the Georgia market at some future unspecified date after sustaining the 1979 losses and following the death of the attorney who had operated HBJ bar review courses in Georgia. No documentation of this decision, however, exists. Conviser also asserts he was unaware of West's withdrawal of its free multistate materials from BRG at the time HBJ purportedly decided to withdraw from Georgia.

78

In early 1980, Conviser and Pelletier got together during a time when BRG and HBJ were still selling bar review courses in Georgia.5 Within a few months, they entered a written agreement on April 22, 1980 ("1980 agreement") which gave BRG the exclusive license to market HBJ's multistate materials in Georgia and the exclusive right to use the Bar/Bri tradename in Georgia. The agreement also contained a provision which required that HBJ not compete with BRG in Georgia and that BRG not compete with HBJ outside of Georgia.6 Under the agreement, HBJ receives $100 per student enrolled and 40% of all revenues over $350. Soon after their agreement, BRG and HBJ announced in their advertising literature that because of their "combination, Bar/Bri Georgia students will, in essence, have the 'best of both worlds.' "

79

Immediately following the 1980 agreement, the price of BRG's course increased from about $150 to over $400. Law students who enrolled in the BRG course and paid the increased bar review course prices during the period April 22, 1980 to June 15, 1984, filed an antitrust suit against BRG, HBJ, Conviser, Pelletier, and others. This class action resulted in a settlement which provided class members with partial refunds. While the lawsuit was pending in 1982, BRG and HBJ modified their 1980 agreement by removing the express covenants not to compete and granting BRG the nonexclusive right to use Bar/Bri materials in Georgia ("1982 agreement"). BRG, however, retained the exclusive right to use the Bar/Bri tradename in conjunction with its bar review course in Georgia.

80

Despite these modifications, HBJ has not competed with BRG in Georgia and has not licensed its multistate materials for use by any other bar review course in Georgia. In addition, BRG has not competed against HBJ outside the Georgia market. The price of the BRG review course has continued to increase also. In 1985 the list price escalated to approximately $825. A group of law students who enrolled in the BRG course in Athens, Georgia from June 15, 1984 to the present initiated this class action alleging that BRG, HBJ and Pelletier engaged in various antitrust violations.7

81

The law-student plaintiffs in this antitrust action could prove that BRG and HBJ violated the antitrust laws in a number of ways. First, they could demonstrate that the 1980 agreement between BRG and HBJ was a per se violation of the antitrust laws and that the conspiratorial agreement continued despite the defendants' 1982 contractual modifications. Next, if the per se claims fail, they could demonstrate that the 1980 and modified 1982 agreements were unreasonable under the rule of reason. They could also establish that BRG and HBJ conspired to or attempted to monopolize, or succeeded in monopolizing, the Georgia market for Georgia bar review courses.

82

The district court held that the 1980 agreement was not illegal under the per se rule; it therefore did not decide whether the BRG-HBJ conspiracy continued. The district court also found that neither the 1980 agreement nor the modified 1982 agreement violated the rule of reason.8

II. Standard of Review

83

My disagreement with the majority begins with its adoption of an improper standard of review in this summary judgment action. In its recitation of the law on antitrust summary judgment, the majority relies on Matsushita Elec. Indust. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986), a predatory pricing action. In Matsushita the Court held that in an action based on a predatory pricing theory "conduct as consistent with permissible competition as with illegal conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an inference of antitrust conspiracy." Id. at 588, 106 S.Ct. at 1357. The plaintiff must therefore provide additional evidence demonstrating that the defendant's conduct was inconsistent with competition. Matsushita's holding is founded on the practical difficulties of differentiating between legitimate and illegitimate business practices (i.e. competitive pricing versus predatory pricing) when the plaintiff's asserted antitrust theory is speculative.

84

Matsushita is one of two recent Supreme Court decisions which have clarified the applicable standard of review in antitrust summary judgment actions which are based on speculative economic theories. See also Monsanto v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 104 S.Ct. 1464, 79 L.Ed.2d 775 (1984) (vertical price fixing action brought by a terminated distributor). Both Matsushita and Monsanto presented the Court with the difficult task of defining the proper evidentiary standard for determining under what factual circumstances an illegal antitrust conspiracy may be inferred from parallel conduct and other circumstantial evidence where direct evidence of conspiracy is lacking.9

85

Both Matsushita and Monsanto, however, are distinguishable from the instant action. Neither case involved a consumer action based upon well-established horizontal per se and rule of reason theories where direct evidence establishes an explicit written agreement between two competitors allocating markets and interfering with independent price setting. Instead, the antitrust claims in Matsushita and Monsanto relied on competitors' predatory pricing and vertical price maintenance theories, respectively, which antitrust scholars and judges have criticized for ensnaring legitimate business practices.10 It is therefore doubtful whether the standards announced in Matsushita and Monsanto apply in situations, such as the instant action, where the direct evidence of concerted action is manifest in explicit written agreements between dominant firms allocating and monopolizing the market and interfering with independent price setting. The 1980 BRG-HBJ agreement is a classic example of the most blatantly anticompetitive practices in which horizontal competitors can engage.11 There is no credible scholarly debate that geographic market allocation and horizontal price-fixing between two dominant firms in an industry are legitimate procompetitive business practices. Thus, the substantive antitrust presumptions that controlled the Court's holding in Matsushita and Monsanto are inapplicable to these types of horizontal agreements whose procompetitive virtues are minimal or non-existent.

86

The standard of review in this summary judgment action is that announced in Celotex v. Catrett, 477 U.S. 317, 106 S.Ct. 2548, 91 L.Ed.2d 265 (1986) and Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 477 U.S. 242, 106 S.Ct. 2505, 91 L.Ed.2d 202 (1986). Under Fed.R.Civ.Proc. 56(c), this court must grant summary judgment for defendants if the plaintiffs "fail to make a showing sufficient to establish the existence of an element essential to [their] case, and on which [they] will bear the burden of proof at trial." Celotex, 477 U.S. at 322, 106 S.Ct. at 2552-53. In determining whether the plaintiffs have met their burden, we must view all the evidence, and inferences drawn from such evidence, in the light most favorable to the plaintiffs and resolve all justifiable inferences in their favor. Anderson, 477 U.S. 242, 253, 106 S.Ct. 2505, 2513, 91 L.Ed.2d 202 (1986); Helicopter Support Systems v. Hughes Helicopter, Inc., 818 F.2d 1530, 1532 (11th Cir.1987). One particular piece of evidence, viewed in isolation, may not be sufficiently probative to justify sending a case to the jury; a review of all the evidence collectively, however, may justify such a result. In addition, we may not weigh conflicting evidence to resolve disputed factual issues. Instead, if a genuine issue of material fact exists, we must deny summary judgment. Helicopter Support Systems, 818 F.2d at 1532 (moving party has burden of demonstrating the absence of a genuine issue of material fact viewing the evidence in the light most favorable to the non-moving party; "A court must deny summary judgment if reasonable minds could differ as to the factual inferences to be drawn from undisputed facts").

87

A thorough review of the entire record indicates that the plaintiffs have produced sufficient evidence to survive summary judgment on their price-fixing, market allocation, rule of reason, and monopolization claims under applicable Supreme Court precedents. Each of these claims relies upon well-established economic theories.12 Further, they support their claims with direct evidence of concerted action (including an explicit written agreement) that excludes the possibility of legitimate independent action. In addition, they have provided substantial expert economic analysis which demonstrates the adverse economic consequences of the defendants' conspiratorial agreement.

III. Per Se Claims

88

The district court's analysis of the plaintiffs' per se claims13 is contrary to well-established antitrust case law. Under binding Supreme Court precedent, the 1980 agreement between HBJ and BRG falls within one of two recognized per se categories: market allocation and price-fixing.14 The district court, however, misapplied the proper test on both claims. In addition, there is sufficient evidence of an unlawful agreement and continuing conspiracy between the defendants to survive a summary judgment motion.

A. HBJ and BRG are Horizontal Competitors

89

As an initial matter, HBJ and BRG argue that the plaintiffs' horizontal per se theories do not apply to them because they are in a vertical supplier/retailer relationship. They further urge that HBJ's asserted unilateral decision to withdraw from the Georgia market in early 1980 instantaneously transformed HBJ's relationship from a horizontal to vertical one thus precluding horizontal per se theories. These arguments, however, are simply disingenuous and meritless.

90

It is firmly established that entities in a seemingly vertical relationship may be capable of horizontal restraints if they are actual or potential competitors.15 During the period 1976-1980, both HBJ and BRG were direct, fierce and antagonistic competitors in the Georgia bar review course market. Because the HBJ and BRG courses were separate and distinguishable brands of comprehensive bar review courses, BRG and HBJ were horizontal competitors engaging in inter-brand competition.16 In addition, HBJ and BRG have always been and continue to be at least potential competitors.17 Simply stated, BRG and HBJ cannot have it both ways--either they are horizontal competitors because HBJ can reenter the Georgia marketplace and compete with BRG or they are co-conspirators acting in concert to prevent such competition between themselves.

91

Further, HBJ and BRG's assertion that HBJ's "withdrawal" from the Georgia market somehow altered BRG's and HBJ's status as actual or potential competitors is disingenuous. Their argument would essentially nullify the per se rule because horizontal competitors could avoid antitrust liability by simply entering into anticompetitive agreements that have vertical aspects. Instead, a court must view an arrangement's economic substance rather than its form.

92

The rationale for each per se rule is an economic analysis of the agreement, an analysis of the potential economic advantages which might motivate the parties to a particular type of agreement. A per se rule is applicable to a particular case if and only if the economic analysis which justifies the rule applies to the particular case.

93

Abadir & Co. v. First Mississippi Corp., 651 F.2d at 426. Given that HBJ vigorously competed and then joined forces with BRG following meetings between Pelletier and Conviser, the indisputable conclusion is that BRG and HBJ were, and continue to be, capable of engaging in per se horizontal restraints.

B. Market Allocation

94

The district court erroneously concluded that to prove a per se violation under a geographic market allocation theory the plaintiffs had to show that BRG and HBJ have sub-divided some relevant market in which they previously competed.18 Because BRG and HBJ did not divide the Georgia marketplace between themselves, the trial court reasoned that no Sherman section 1 violation occurred. The court, however, made an erroneous legal distinction between the terms "divide" and "allocate."

95

Well-established case law demonstrates that the allocation of markets or sub-markets by competitors is a per se antitrust violation. In United States v. Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 92 S.Ct. 1126, 31 L.Ed.2d 515 (1972), the Supreme Court held that agreements between competitors to allocate territories to minimize competition are per se unlawful:

96

One of the classic examples of a per se violation of Sec. 1 is an agreement between competitors at the same level of the market structure to allocate territories in order to minimize competition.... This Court has reiterated time and time again that "[h]orizontal territorial limitations ... are naked restraints of trade with no purpose except stifling of competition." Such limitations are per se violations of the Sherman Act.

97

Id. at 608, 92 S.Ct. at 1133-34 (emphasis added) (citations omitted). See also E. Sullivan & J. Harrison, Understanding Antitrust and Its Economic Implications, Sec. 4.14 at 111 (1988) ("A horizontal market division is created when competitors agree not to compete in a designated market."). The defendants in Topco did not divide a market in which they had previously competed; they simply agreed to allocate markets. See also Gainesville Utilities v. Florida Power & Light Co., 573 F.2d 292, 299-300 (5th Cir.1978) (horizontal market division per se violation), cert. denied, 439 U.S. 966, 99 S.Ct. 454, 58 L.Ed.2d 424 (1978). Thus, market division is simply a subset of market allocation both of which are per se antitrust violations.19

98

In this action, HBJ and BRG allocated designated markets: BRG received the Georgia market while HBJ received the balance of the United States. Each agreed not to compete in the other's respective market. The district court therefore erred in failing to classify this market allocation agreement as a per se violation.

C. Price-Fixing Claim

99

The plaintiffs also claim that BRG and HBJ entered into their 1980 agreement with the primary purpose of eliminating price competition between themselves in the Georgia marketplace. They assert that the license fee and revenue-sharing agreement between BRG and HBJ is the mechanism that facilitates the defendants' purpose in raising the price of bar review courses and distributing the resulting profits. BRG and HBJ disavow any intent to restrain trade and claim that their agreement is "nothing more than an ordinary copyright royalty arrangement" which courts have "routinely sustained." The district court held there was no per se violation because the agreement neither explicitly set prices nor was it inherently anticompetitive.20

100

The district court's analysis of the plaintiffs' price-fixing claim is incomplete in at least two important respects. First, the fact that the agreement between the defendants did not explicitly address pricing and HBJ did not have the express right under the agreement to be consulted about the prices BRG charged for bar review courses, does not exclude the possibility of a price-fixing violation. Second, the district court erred in finding that the revenue-sharing agreement was not inherently anticompetitive because the record establishes that the purpose and effect of the agreement was to increase the price of bar review courses.

101

It is clear that a horizontal price-fixing violation does not require that the defendants literally fix prices. Instead, "[u]nder the Sherman Act a combination formed for the purpose and with the effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of a commodity in interstate or foreign commerce is illegal per se." United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 223, 60 S.Ct. 811, 844, 84, L.Ed. 1129 (1940). For instance, price-fixing results when competitors agree to some non-price restrictions that directly and adversely affect the market prices for their goods or services.21 Such indirect methods of raising prices injure consumers as much as direct, overt price setting.

102

In contrast to such indirect methods, the combination of the defendants' licensing and revenue-sharing agreements has a direct upward effect on price because it requires BRG to set the price of its bar review course above $350 before revenue-sharing begins. It also totally eliminates HBJ's incentive to compete with BRG in Georgia. First, HBJ has little incentive to compete with BRG because any resulting price competition would reduce HBJ's profits under the agreement's revenue-sharing provision. Second, BRG has the exclusive right to use the Bar/Bri tradename in Georgia thus precluding HBJ from using its own multistate materials and its own tradename. The combination of the licensing and revenue-sharing provisions have the effect of stifling competition and maintaining BRG's (and indirectly HBJ's) dominance in Georgia.

103

The second error in the district court's analysis relates to the possible justifications for the defendants' conduct. The district court correctly noted that because some horizontal agreements have procompetitive potential, not all horizontal agreements among actual or potential competitors that have an impact on price are per se violations. For example, some joint ventures and other cooperative arrangements are not per se violations because an agreement on price is necessary to market the product.22

104

In determining whether a challenged practice is a per se violation or subject to a rule of reason, a court must inquire into whether the practice always or almost always tends to raise price and restrict output or instead is likely to assist the creation of economic efficiency. Rigid line drawing must be avoided and close attention given to procompetitive, efficiency-creating integration that is accomplished as the result of an outwardly anticompetitive, yet ancillary, restraint. National Bancard Corp. v. VISA, U.S.A., Inc., 779 F.2d 592 (11th Cir.1986), cert. denied, 479 U.S. 923, 107 S.Ct. 329, 93 L.Ed.2d 301 (1986).

105

Here, in contrast, the record is devoid of any evidence that the agreement between HBJ and BRG was ancillary or that it had some procompetitive, efficiency-creating potential. Furthermore, there is no evidence that it was necessary for HBJ and BRG to combine their resources to provide a bar review course in Georgia particularly when they had competed for several years prior to their price war. The use of restrictive covenants in the 1980 agreement further buttresses the inference that the defendants' purpose in allocating the Georgia market was to reduce competition between themselves and ultimately to raise prices and reduce output.23

106

It is worth reiterating that the 1980 agreement totally eliminated price and inter-brand competition between HBJ and BRG in the Georgia market and there are no apparent economies of scale or other cost savings to counterbalance this anticompetitive result. HBJ could have sold its materials to BRG without entering such a blatantly anticompetitive agreement.24 Instead, the two principal competitors in the Georgia market have accomplished through their written agreement and subsequent actions what the antitrust laws were designed to prevent: injury to the consumer.

107

The evidence establishes that the 1980 agreement between BRG and HBJ is per se illegal under binding Supreme Court precedent. The written agreement has the effect of reducing price competition in Georgia and markets into which BRG might have otherwise entered absent the agreement. The agreement also has no redeeming procompetitive virtues. Thus, the trial court erred by too narrowly construing the rule against horizontal price fixing and should have condemned the defendants' agreement as being per se illegal.25

IV. Rule of Reason Claim

108

Although the 1980 agreement is a per se violation, the plaintiffs may also show that the 1980 agreement and its subsequent 1982 modifications violate the rule of reason. The district court found that neither the 1980 nor the reformulated 1982 agreements violated the rule of reason because the plaintiffs failed to demonstrate any actual anticompetitive effects. The district court erred in its findings and also failed to apply the proper analysis under the rule of reason.

109

Under the rule of reason, a "factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition." Continental T.V. Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49, 97 S.Ct. 2549, 2557, 53 L.Ed.2d 568 (1978). Although the rule of reason will often require a careful balancing of a challenged restraint's harms, benefits, and alternatives, a court can readily condemn a challenged restraint on summary judgment when the restraint directly limits competition on price or output and has no procompetitive justification. P. Areeda, Antitrust Law, p 1508, at 403 (1986); see also NCAA, 468 U.S. at 109, 104 S.Ct. at 2964. Under the rule of reason, a sliding scale has developed which permits antitrust plaintiffs to demonstrate a lower threshold level of anticompetitive effect the more egregious the defendants' challenged practice or restraint. A demonstration of anticompetitive effect or market power, however, may not be necessary in cases where the challenged restraints are sufficiently "naked" in the sense that they directly restrain price or output.

110

A. The Rule of Reason Under Indiana Federation of Dentists

111

Under the rule of reason as enunciated in FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 106 S.Ct. 2009, 90 L.Ed.2d 445 (1986),26 the plaintiffs in this action can demonstrate an antitrust violation in one of two ways. The first requires that the plaintiffs demonstrate that the 1980 agreement between BRG and HBJ imposed a "naked" restriction on output or price; in this instance, the plaintiffs would not have to define a relevant market or show market power. BRG and HBJ, however, would have to provide a countervailing procompetitive virtue to avoid liability. Under the second method, if the agreement is not sufficiently "naked," the plaintiffs can show actual detrimental effects, such as a reduction of output or increased price, instead of an inquiry into market power.

B. BRG-HBJ Agreement is a "Naked" Restraint

112

Under the first method, the 1980 BRG-HBJ agreement is a blatant "naked" restriction on output because it allocated markets and thus prevented HBJ from selling its bar review materials to any course provider other than BRG in the Georgia market. This along with the exclusive tradename provision perpetuated BRG's, and indirectly HBJ's, economic dominance in the Georgia bar review course market. The plaintiffs therefore did not have to provide evidence of a relevant market or market power to prevail on their claim. Instead, the burden shifted to defendants to provide evidence of some procompetitive efficiency-enhancing virtue to their agreement, which they failed to do. The district court erred in holding that the BRG-HBJ agreements were not presumptively anticompetitive under the rule of reason.

C. Anticompetitive Effects

113

Under the second method, the plaintiffs must prevail because they have demonstrated actual detrimental effects:27 the price of bar review courses has increased dramatically with no sufficient cost-based explanation and BRG and HBJ's non-competition agreement has reduced consumer choice and reduced output.

114

The plaintiffs introduced evidence of a dramatic price increase which immediately followed the defendants' 1980 agreement. The district court rejected the conclusion that this price increase was an anticompetitive result of the defendants' agreement.28 A review of the record, however, indicates that a genuine issue of material fact regarding actual and continuing anticompetitive effects exists thus precluding summary judgment for the defendants on the plaintiffs' rule of reason claims.29

1. Price Increases

115

The record indicates that the price of BRG's bar review course in Georgia has increased from $150 in 1979 to a list price of $825 in 1985. This increase in price is obviously detrimental to consumers of Georgia bar review courses yet the district court held that the increase does not necessarily establish anticompetitive effect because BRG's costs may have increased because West Publishing no longer made its free multistate materials available.30 The court's analysis, however, neglects the anticompetitive effects inherent in the defendants' licensing fee and revenue-sharing provisions contained in both the 1980 and 1982 agreements.

116

The district court is correct in concluding that the possibility of anticompetitive effect exists and that the price increase of BRG's bar review course may be attributable, in part, to the cost of multistate materials that BRG must now bear due to West Publishing's decision to charge for its previously free materials.31 These increased costs, of course, are increased revenues for HBJ. Under their agreements, BRG pays HBJ $100 per student enrolled and BRG and HBJ jointly share any price increases above $350. Thus, any price increase imposed on BRG bar review consumers above $350 results in increased revenues to both BRG and HBJ. For instance, for each bar review course BRG sells at the 1985 list price of $825, HBJ receives $190 (40% of $475) plus the $100 per student licensing fee. At the $825 list price, HBJ receives a total of $290 per course sold while BRG receives the balance of $535 per course. The revenue-sharing provision, therefore, minimizes HBJ's incentive to compete with BRG because any resulting price competition would reduce HBJ's profits under the agreement. Similarly, the revenue-sharing provision also minimizes HBJ's incentive to license its multistate materials to other bar review courses in Georgia because such courses would compete with BRG and further reduce HBJ's profits.

117

Thus, it is a disputed factual issue whether the price increases resulted from reduced competition following HBJ's "withdrawal" or from BRG having to pay additional production costs and salaries. It may be that a large portion of BRG's increased "costs" may simply be HBJ's share of the increased revenues resulting from less price competition. The defendants failed to offer any evidence to rebut the strong inference that the price increases resulted in large part from the defendants' agreements and their adverse effects on competition in the Georgia bar review markets.

2. Bar/Bri Tradename

118

In addition to price increases, BRG's retention of the exclusive right to use the Bar/Bri tradename on Georgia materials under the 1982 agreement effectively prevents HBJ from competing with BRG or licensing its multistate materials to any other potential providers of bar review courses in Georgia. In fact, the Bar/Bri tradename has displaced the BRG tradename making BRG and Bar/Bri synonymous as a common business entity in the Georgia marketplace. The defendants' argument that another competing bar review in Georgia could use the Bar/Bri materials under another tradename such as "HBJ Georgia" and compete effectively is highly speculative.

D. Summary

119

In sum, the plaintiffs have demonstrated that the 1980 agreement and its modifications impose sufficiently "naked" restraints on price and output making an elaborate inquiry into market analysis unnecessary. Even if the 1980 agreement and its 1982 modifications were legally not sufficiently "naked," the plaintiffs have demonstrated sufficient actual, sustained detrimental effects on competition to survive summary judgment.

V. Sherman Section Two Claims

120

The plaintiffs allege that the defendants conspired to monopolize,32 attempted to monopolize,33 and monopolized34 the Georgia market (and relevant submarkets) for bar review courses that prepare law students for the Georgia bar. The district court granted summary judgment in defendants' favor on these counts because it held that the plaintiffs failed to properly identify the relevant product and geographic markets. The court refused to consider additional economic evidence on these claims despite considering such evidence under the plaintiffs' rule of reason claim.

A. Monopoly Power

121

Under Sherman section 2, a plaintiff must demonstrate that the defendant(s) have either monopoly power or substantial market power in a relevant product and geographic market.35 In its attempt to evaluate what degree of economic power the defendants exercised in the relevant market, the district court discounted most of the plaintiffs' totally uncontested evidence.36 The district court held that "the entirety of Plaintiffs' effort to identify the proper product and geographic markets is contained in the affidavit of Dr. William Henry.... Doctor Henry's affidavit is insufficient to identify or justify a proper product or geographic market." Order, January 9, 1987 at 12. The court held that Dr. Henry's conclusions were "valueless" because he defined the product market in a "narrow and seemingly artificial manner without economic justifications." Id. The court also rejected Dr. Henry's conclusion that Athens, Georgia was a relevant submarket. The court stated that Dr. Henry's analysis did not address "that area in which the product is offered, but rather limits its consideration to the place where the course is administered during the school year." Id.

122

The district court did not include in its market analysis the deposition of expert witness Prof. David Kamerschen (including exhibits),37 the depositions and affidavits of members of the law student class, and the survey data and affidavit provided by Prof. Ponsoldt. The court also neglected Dr. Henry's second affidavit and the defendants' own marketing literature and deposition testimony. These additional materials provide a vivid description of the product and geographic market structure issues relevant to the resolution of the claims in this case.

1. Geographic Submarkets

123

The court erred in failing to recognize Athens, Georgia as a relevant submarket for Sherman section 2 analysis. The district court correctly notes that BRG offers its review course on a statewide basis.38 The district court, however, rejected the plaintiffs' contention that Athens, Georgia was a relevant submarket39 despite uncontested expert testimony and survey data which indicates that law student preferences and high transportation costs separate Athens from the Atlanta and Macon markets. In addition, 1986-87 survey data show that approximately 90% of University of Georgia third year law students take the BRG course during the winter term when they are still enrolled in school.40 Yet, the district court discounted all this evidence.

124

Further, the record indicates that BRG and HBJ combined for at least 80% of the Athens market prior to their agreement. Pelletier Deposition at 130. The district court confirms this fact stating that the "vast majority" of University of Georgia law students who took a bar review course conducted in Athens, took either the "Harcourt or the BRG course" in 1979. Subsequent survey data of University of Georgia law students, who basically constitute the entire Athens market, indicates that BRG has over 95% of the Athens market. Ponsoldt Affidavit, Record Vol. 3, Tab 31, at 3.

2. Relevant Product Market

125

The plaintiffs presented evidence that the relevant product market is comprehensive bar review courses including lectures and written materials that prepare students to take the Georgia bar exam.41 The district court, however, held that the plaintiffs failed to establish a relevant product market.

126

In Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962), the Court stated:

127

The outer boundaries of a product market are determined by the reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it. However, within this broad market, well-defined submarkets may exist which, in themselves, constitute product market for antitrust purposes. The boundaries of such a submarket may be determined by examining such practical indicia as industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the products's peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors.

128

Id. at 325, 82 S.Ct. at 1523-24. The district court's analysis is contrary to Brown because the plaintiff presented evidence indicating that (1) University of Georgia law students perceived no reasonable alternatives to the comprehensive BRG review course; (2) third year law students (in particular winter semester third year students) are distinct consumers, and (3) law student consumers were insensitive to price increases because they continued to purchase the BRG course even after large price increases. The defendants' own advertising literature and deposition statements also reflect their perception that comprehensive bar review courses that prepare students for the Georgia bar constitute a relevant product market.

129

This uncontroverted evidence provides substantial support for the plaintiffs' Sherman section 2 claims. Thus, the district court erred in granting summary judgment for the defendants because the plaintiffs' evidence raises a genuine issue of fact regarding whether the defendants violated Sherman section 2.

VI. Conclusion

130

In conclusion, the district court failed to adequately analyze the plaintiffs' per se price-fixing and market allocation claims. The plaintiffs have demonstrated that BRG and HBJ conspired to restrain trade and entered an explicit written agreement in 1980 which was per se illegal. It remains a factual issue whether the defendants have withdrawn from this conspiratorial agreement. The trial court also erred in failing to properly analyze the plaintiffs' rule of reason claim. The plaintiffs have presented sufficient evidence that the defendants entered an agreement that directly restrained competition in the Georgia bar review market. The plaintiffs have also demonstrated actual anticompetitive effects arising from the agreement. This same economic evidence supports the plaintiffs' Sherman section 2 claims. I would reverse the district court's summary judgment and remand to the district court for a trial on all of the foregoing issues.

*

The Order amending this opinion is published at 893 F.2d 293

*

Honorable Duross Fitzpatrick, U.S. District Judge for the Middle District of Georgia, sitting by designation

1

BRG includes Bar Review Group, Inc. and BRG publications, Inc., all Georgia corporations

Pelletier formed BRG in 1979 for the sole purpose of offering bar review courses to Georgia bar applicants.

2

Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides: "Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal...."

3

The district court noted that these theories were improperly pled as separate counts because the plaintiffs only have one cause of action for an alleged section 1 violation of the Sherman Act. However, for ease of reference, the district court referred to the designations chosen by plaintiffs

4

Section 2 of the Sherman Act provides: "Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed [to have violated this Act]...."

5

Fed.R.Civ.P. 11 provides, in pertinent part:

If a pleading, motion, or other paper is signed in violation of this rule, the court, upon motion or upon its own initiative, shall impose upon the person who signed it, a represented party, or both, an appropriate sanction, which may include an order to pay to the other party or parties the amount of the reasonable expenses incurred because of the filing of the pleading, motion, or other paper, including a reasonable attorney's fee.

6

The affidavit states:

Dr. William Henry, being duly sworn, deposes and says:

1

I am Professor of Finance in the College of Business Administration at Georgia State University with a Ph.D. degree in economics from North Carolina State University, and give this affidavit in the above-captioned matter.

2

I have reviewed the depositions of the plaintiffs in this action, the deposition of Ronald Pelletier, the enrollment contracts produced by the defendants, and the deoposition of Professor David Kamershen taken in the case of Edwards et al. v. BRG of Georgia, Inc., C.A. No. 82-13-Ath together with the exhibits thereto.

3

Upon review of the depositions of the named plaintiffs and the deposition of Ronald Pelletier it is apparent that nearly all students at University of Georgia School of Law take the defendants' bar review course. Because the students taking the course are also enrolled as full-time students at the law school in Athens, it is not realistic to expect that they could reasonable [sic] take a course offered outside the Athens area. Further, Ronald Pelletier testified that defendants accounted for at least eighty percent of the sales of bar review courses in the Athens area.

4

I conclude that a comprehensive bar review course which includes lectures and written material offered in Athens, Georgia to prepare students to take the Georgia bar examination is the relevant product market and that Athens is a relevant geographic market for purposes of ecomonic analysis. I further conclude that defendants have and have had the power to control prices in the market, and that defendants therefore have monopoly power in the relevant geographic and product markets.

This the 12th day of May, 1986.

/s/ William R. Henry

Dr. William Henry

1

I concur in Part II of the majority opinion (upholding district court's denial of Rule 11 sanctions). I disagree, however, with the majority's conclusion in Part I that the district court's denial of class certification was not an abuse of discretion. The premise of the district court's order was that the plaintiffs "may lack financial commitment sufficient for adequate investigation and trial preparation in light of the court's ruling [granting summary judgment on all counts except the rule of reason claim]." The record reflects that the plaintiffs' counsel was qualified and experienced, and prepared this case from its inception in a competent and professional manner. The plaintiffs' alleged lack of financial commitment was simply not a factor in their trial counsels' presentation of their case. I believe that the district court's misperceptions regarding the evidence necessary to establish the asserted antitrust violations, discussed infra, resulted in the court erroneously denying class certification based on the plaintiffs' purported "lack of financial commitment." I would therefore reverse the district court on this issue

2

Prior to 1979, BRG's predecessor, defendant Bar Review Group, Inc., offered the bar review course in Georgia. During 1979, Pelletier formed two corporations: BRG of Georgia (BRG) and BRG Publications. For purposes of this opinion, references to the defendant BRG includes Pelletier as well

3

HBJ originally retailed its bar review courses directly to consumers but has since modified its retailing strategy to include about 19 licensees who have the exclusive or non-exclusive right to provide HBJ bar review courses. HBJ does not concurrently offer its course at retail in competition with any of these licensees

4

The review courses were administered in three cities, Atlanta, Athens, and Macon, where law schools were located

5

Their first meeting was arranged by one of Conviser's attorneys in Chicago who had contacted Pelletier by phone. Conviser flew to Atlanta, Georgia and met Pelletier at the Coach & Six restaurant where they discussed "in passing" the possibility of Bar/Bri purchasing BRG or BRG buying HBJ's Georgia operations. Record, Vol. 1, Tab 2, at 10-11. Pelletier later flew to Chicago where he and Conviser discussed a licensing arrangement or buy-out. Id. Pelletier returned to Atlanta where a third meeting was held to discuss a possible licensing arrangement. Id

6

The 1980 agreement contained two provisions one termed a "Covenant Not to Compete" and the other entitled "Other Ventures." Record, Vol. 2, Tab 13 at E10, E15. The former required HBJ not to directly or indirectly "own, manage, operate, join, invest, control, or participate in or be connected as an officer, employee, partner, director, independent contractor or otherwise with any business which is operating or participating in the preparation of candidates for the Georgia State Bar Examination." Id. at E10. The latter required BRG not to compete against HBJ in states in which HBJ currently operated outside the state of Georgia. Id. at E15

7

The nine count complaint alleges the defendants engaged in: (1) horizontal price-fixing; (2) geographic market allocations; (3) concerted refusals to deal; (4) an unreasonable joint venture; (5) a conspiracy to monopolize bar review written materials and lecture services in Georgia; (6) an attempt to monopolize bar review written materials and lecture services in Georgia; (7) monopolization of bar review written materials and lecture services in Georgia; (8) a conspiracy to monopolize bar review written materials and lecture services nationwide; and (9) an attempt to monopolize bar review written materials and lecture services nationwide

8

In its January 9, 1987 order the court granted the defendants' motion for summary judgment on counts 1-9. The court, however, permitted the plaintiffs to recast counts 1-4 under the rule of reason

9

The common concern in Matsushita and Monsanto is that a court's denial of summary judgment based merely on speculative inferences from ambiguous evidence could deter or penalize perfectly legitimate and procompetitive conduct. Because legitimate price-cutting is the "very essence of competition," allowing "mistaken inferences" to result in antitrust liability chills "the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect." Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 594, 106 S.Ct. at 1360 (citing Monsanto ). The Supreme Court therefore adopted more exacting evidentiary standards to separate permissible procompetitive business practices from proscribed anticompetitive practices in antitrust actions based on business conduct that facially supports either practice. Consequently, both cases reinvigorated the use of summary judgment to summarily dismiss certain antitrust actions based on circumstantial evidence and speculative economic theories

10

Criticism of the broad application of predatory pricing theories abounds. See, e.g., R. Blair & D. Kaserman, Antitrust Economics, 121-128 (1985) (predatory pricing may preserve or enhance, but cannot create, market power); R. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself, 144-59 (1978) (debunking most predatory pricing theories); R. Posner, Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective, 184-96 (1976) (narrowly limiting predation to practices designed to exclude an equally or more efficient competitor). Vertical price-fixing has also been severely critiqued. See, e.g., R. Blair & D. Kaserman, Law and Economics of Vertical Integration and Control, 157-61 (1983) (law condemns vertical price maintenance despite potentially beneficial economic effects); R. Bork, supra, at 280-98 (virtually all vertical restraints benefit consumers and should be lawful)

11

Notably, the plaintiffs in this action allege a conspiracy between two corporations and their respective officers. This situation is unlike the predatory pricing scheme involving twenty-one defendants that the Supreme Court found implausible in Matsushita

12

The plaintiffs' price-fixing and market allocation claims are the types that courts and economists have long condemned as per se violations of the Sherman Act. Their rule of reason and monopolization claims are similarly founded upon widely accepted economic principles

13

Per Se rules are appropriate only for conduct which is manifestly anticompetitive and should be "invoked when surrounding circumstances make the likelihood of anticompetitive conduct so great as to render unjustified further examination of the challenged conduct." National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents of University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 103-04, 104 S.Ct. 2948, 2961, 82 L.Ed.2d 70 (1984)

14

The Supreme Court has applied the per se rule to geographic market allocation and horizontal price-fixing because such practices are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of an industry is necessary to establish their illegality. National Soc. of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692, 98 S.Ct. 1355, 1365, 55 L.Ed.2d 637 (1978)

15

Abadir & Co. v. First Mississippi Corp., 651 F.2d 422, 426-27 (5th Cir.Unit A July 1981) (competitors not allowed to turn an otherwise horizontal agreement vertical by setting up a licensing corporation to impose market allocation agreements); see, e.g., U.S. v. Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 92 S.Ct. 1126, 1134, 31 L.Ed.2d 515 (1972) (cooperative buying association which allocates territories violates horizontal per se rule); U.S. v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350, 87 S.Ct. 1847, 1850, 18 L.Ed.2d 1238 (1967) (characterizing licensor-licensee relationship as horizontal where licensees own substantially all stock of licensor)

16

Agreements between horizontal competitors that affect inter-brand competition are the "primary concern of antitrust law." Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 52 n. 19, 97 S.Ct. 2549, 2558 n. 19, 53 L.Ed.2d 568 (1977)

17

Both provide the same type of service, bar review courses, and both are capable of providing their services in the same geographic locations (absent their agreements)

18

The district court stated that:

Neither agreement between BRG and [HBJ] constitutes the sort of market or customer allocation agreement which has been recognized as a basis of per se liability. Cf. Topco, 405 U.S. 596 [92 S.Ct. 1126]. This is not a situation where competitors divided up a market in which both have previously done business, each taking a portion of a market. BRG has never done business outside the state of Georgia, and nothing in the record suggests that it ever intended to do so. [HBJ] as noted has done business virtually nationwide, but withdrew from the Georgia market following the 1980 agreement between BRG and [HBJ]. Thus, the only market ever claimed by both Defendants is the state of Georgia, and clearly the state of Georgia was not divided up under either the 1980 or 1982 agreements.

Order, January 9, 1987 at 8 (emphasis added).

19

To use the district court's parlance, BRG and HBJ divided the Georgia market by allocating 0% for HBJ and 100% for BRG and divided the national market by allocating 100% for HBJ and 0% for BRG

20

The district court held that:

the agreement is not a classic form of price fixing where two competitors agree what price they will charge for their products. On the contrary, neither agreement explicitly addresses the factor of price, and [HBJ] has never had any right under either the 1980 or 1982 agreement to be consulted about the price of the BRG course. While it is true that the agreement of two competitors to "pool" their products may exert an upward influence on price, such an agreement is not inherently anticompetitive, and in a given setting could actually be procompetitive.

Order, January 9, 1987, at 7-8.

21

See, e.g., Catalano Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643, 100 S.Ct. 1925, 64 L.Ed.2d 580 (1980) (horizontal agreement to terminate the practice of giving credit falls squarely within the traditional per se rule against price-fixing); National Society of Prof. Eng. v. U.S., 435 U.S. 679, 98 S.Ct. 1355, 55 L.Ed.2d 637 (1978) (agreement that interferes with setting of price by free market forces is illegal on its face)

22

See, e.g., National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents of University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 101, 104 S.Ct. 2948, 2960, 82 L.Ed.2d 70 (1984) (horizontal restraints on competition necessary if product is to be available); Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 21-22, 99 S.Ct. 1551, 1563, 60 L.Ed.2d 1 (1979) (horizontal licensing arrangement created product which was "greater than the sum of its parts")

23

See Citizens Publishing Co. v. United States, 394 U.S. 131, 134-36, 89 S.Ct. 927, 928-29, 22 L.Ed.2d 148 (1969) (market allocation agreement designed to prevent commercial rivalry and support price fixing conspiracy)

24

See infra note 31

25

Because the district court erred in finding that the 1980 agreement did not constitute a per se violation, it did not address whether the 1982 modified agreement constituted a withdrawal from or abandonment of the conspiracy. In United States v. Kissel, 218 U.S. 601, 31 S.Ct. 124, 54 L.Ed. 1168 (1910), the Supreme Court held that antitrust conspiracies may continue in time beyond the original conspiratorial agreement until either the conspiracy's objectives are abandoned or succeed. Id. at 608-09, 31 S.Ct. at 126. For example, a conspiracy continues so long as one or more conspirators continue to receive payments under a collusive contract because the conspirators continue to realize a central and obvious objective of the conspiracy (i.e. illicit profits). United States v. Dynalectric Co., 859 F.2d 1559, 1563-69 (11th Cir.1988); United States v. Aquafredda, 834 F.2d 915, 919 (11th Cir.1987), cert. denied sub nom., Agostino v. United States, --- U.S. ----, 108 S.Ct. 1278, 99 L.Ed.2d 489 (1988). In the absence of proof of withdrawal, the conspirators are presumed to continue in their conspiracy particularly where they continue to share the fruits of their conspiracy, in this case through the revenue-sharing provision in the 1980 and 1982 agreements. Dynalectric, 859 F.2d at 1563-69; Aquafredda, 834 F.2d at 919 (antitrust defendants' continued sharing of revenues and professional and social affiliations permits inference of continued conspiracy). Thus, it is an unsettled factual issue whether the conspiratorial objectives manifest in the 1980 agreement between HBJ and BRG have continued despite the supposedly ameliorative modifications made in 1982

26

In Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 106 S.Ct. 2009, 90 L.Ed.2d 445 (1986) a group of dentists decided to stop supplying x-rays of their patients' mouths to the insurance company paying the bill. The Supreme Court held that this practice is an illegal horizontal agreement that withheld from dental customers a particular service the customers desired. "Absent some countervailing procompetitive virtue--such as, for example, the creation of efficiencies in the operation of a market or the provision of goods and services, such an agreement limiting consumer choice by impeding the 'ordinary give and take of the market place' cannot be sustained under the Rule of Reason." 476 U.S. at 459, 106 S.Ct. at 2018 (citations omitted). Additionally, the Court reiterated that the FTC's absence of specific findings regarding market definition and market power does not preclude, as a matter of law, a finding that the dentists unlawfully restrained trade. Id. at 460, 106 S.Ct. at 2018-19. Instead, actual proof of detrimental effects, such as a reduction of output, can obviate the need for an inquiry into market power. Id. at 460-61, 106 S.Ct. at 2019

27

Because they have shown anticompetitive effects, the plaintiffs would not have to establish a relevant market or that the defendants had market power

28

Instead, the district court held "it is as reasonable to assume that the price increase reflected [additional multistate] costs as it is to assume that the higher prices were merely to gouge the consumers." Order, July 8, 1987 at 5. The trial court also held that the plaintiffs failed to demonstrate that the defendants' modified contractual arrangement had a "present anticompetitive effect in a relevant geographic and product market." Order, July 8, 1987, at 7 (emphasis added)

29

Plaintiffs in a rule of reason case do not have to demonstrate a present anticompetitive effect in a specifically-defined product and geographic market if they can establish the existence of anticompetitive effects or purpose during the time period that the anticompetitive practices were allegedly in effect. These anticompetitive effects can be inferred from the price increases following the HBJ-BRG agreement (and the resulting reduction in the number of bar review courses sold), the licensing and revenue-sharing provisions, and the elimination of consumer choice through HBJ's withdrawal from the Georgia market

30

The district court concluded that "[u]nder the circumstances, it is fair to conclude that the possibility of anticompetitive effect exists, but that such effect cannot be presumed from the contract itself." Order, July 8, 1987, at 4

31

An important factual issue is whether BRG's and HBJ's agreements are necessary for either's competitive survival. First, no evidence exists to explain why BRG had to use Bar/Bri's multistate materials much less have the exclusive right to the Bar/Bri tradename. Other sources of multistate materials existed. For instance, West Publishing's materials were still available albeit not free. Pelletier Deposition, at 73. Second, although HBJ would forego income by not selling its multistate materials to some other bar review course in Georgia, no legitimate reasons exist to explain why it was necessary for HBJ to form an agreement with its only rival in Georgia that contains blatantly anticompetitive licensing, revenue-sharing, and market allocation provisions. A plausible explanation is BRG's and HBJ's collective desire to profit by eliminating their rivalry and sharing the increased revenues that would result from BRG's new-found dominance in the Georgia market

32

A conspiracy to monopolize requires (1) proof of concerted action deliberately entered into with the specific intent to accomplish the unlawful result of achieving a monopoly; and (2) the commission of at least one overt act in furtherance of the conspiracy. Under a conspiracy theory, the defendants do not have to attain monopoly power nor would they have to obtain monopoly power if their conspiracy had been successful. L. Sullivan, Handbook on the Law of Antitrust, 132-34 (1977)

33

Attempted monopolization is an offense distinct from monopolization which requires (1) a specific intent to monopolize and (2) a dangerous probability of success. Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143, 153, 72 S.Ct. 181, 186, 96 L.Ed. 162 (1951). The most important evidence of defendants' specific intent to monopolize is anticompetitive conduct. A dangerous probability of success is measured by a defendant's possession of substantial market power

34

The offense of monopoly under section 2 of the Sherman Act has two elements: (1) the possession of monopoly power in a relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of superior product, business acumen, or historic accident. United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 1703-04, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966)

35

Monopoly power is defined as the power to control price or exclude competition and is measured by reference to the relevant market. United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391, 76 S.Ct. 994, 1005, 100 L.Ed. 1264. Market share is the traditional measure of market and monopoly power. United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 571, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 1704, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966) (90% share of relevant market constitutes monopoly power, over 80% share a "substantial monopoly"). The determination of the relevant product and geographic markets (and a defendant's market share), however, is not an exact science and mathematical precision may, at times, yield to administrative convenience

36

The defendants submitted no evidence to rebut the plaintiffs' market structure analysis

37

Kamerschen's deposition was the principal economic evidence upon which the first class action was based

38

"[T]he record discloses that BRG's course is marketed statewide, and is offered at various statewide locations both during the school year and following the close of the school year." Order, January 1, 1987 at 12. The court however failed to consider whether Georgia is a relevant geographic market despite evidence suggesting such a conclusion

39

The Supreme Court in United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966), stated that under Sherman section 2 "there may be submarkets that are separate economic entities."

40

Prof. Ponsoldt conducted the survey of all third year students at the University of Georgia. The survey indicated it was being conducted in "context of a pending federal antitrust case against certain bar review course companies." Record, Vol. 2, Tab 31 at 8. 63 of the 170 third year students responded. Id. at 3

41

See, e.g., Henry Affidavit, Record, Vol. 2, Tab 17